From: Bruce Mitchell [bruceamitchell@yahoo.com] Sent: Wednesday, April 07, 2004 12:48 PM To: rule-comments@sec.gov Subject: File No. S7-07-04: Competitive Developments in the Options Markets Ladies and Gentlemen: I am providing comments to the above referenced release for your consideration. I am a professional off-floor options trader. If you have additional questions concerning my comments please contact me. General Comments As the release discusses, in general, electronic trading, intermarket competition, and added exchanges have dramatically improved the efficiency, i.e. narrower spreads, of options markets in recent years. Nonetheless, in my view, payment for order flow, specialist guarantees and internalization have not aided that dynamic and do present potential negatives for the options markets in the future. In addition, on a related subject that raises similar issues to ones covered by the release (but not specifically solicited), I would like to note that index options, (e.g. SPX) which represent by far the highest volume of options traded and a significant percentage overall have not enjoyed the benefits or increases in efficiency that have occurred in the market as a whole. I believe this is an important area of potential improvement and attention for the Commission. Index Options Let me quote from the release: "Today, virtually all actively traded equity options trade on multiple markets, a development that has enhanced competition among the options exchanges."' This is patently inaccurate. The highest volume option traded -- the SPX -- is traded only on the CBOE. And, the spreads commonly present in the SPX market are huge compared to the average NBBO spreads (i.e. $0.18) referenced by the release. The SPX is almost never below $0.50 and is usually between $1.00 and $2.00. This is a direct result of the lack of competition in the product stemming from the fact that it trades exclusively on the CBOE under contractual arrangements with S&P. This area needs to be exposed to the same dynamics as the rest of the market for the benefit of the customer. Payment for Order Flow In my view, payment for order flow has three significant problems: (1) It introduces a potential conflict of interest for the broker-dealer and its best-execution obligation; (2) it may reduce the long-term liquidity and efficiency of options markets by narrowing the profitibility of market making to the point that there are fewer market-maker participants long-term; and (3) it disconnects the party delivering the value (i.e. the customer and his order) from the party receiving value for the order (i.e. the order introducing firm). History suggests that the potential conflict of interest presented will almost certainly, at some point, lead to the abuse of the conflict of interest at the expense of the customer. And, it is extremely difficult for the customer to be aware of the abuse of that conflict, to prove the abuse and to receive appropriate restituition. So, it would likely be better if the potential for abuse were removed. Markets work best and are most efficient when there is multiple party participation and not overmuch concentration in one or few parties' hands. While options markets have become much more efficient in recent years to the benefit of the customer, dynamics that lead to overmuch concentration could ultimately work to the customer's detriment. The reduction of profit potential from market making presented by payment for order flow, on the margin, works to further this undesirable dynamic. It particularly affects diverse, smaller scale market makers, who have to live with often inequitable rules governing order flow payment revenue allocations. Diverse market makers presence in the markets, long-term would be beneficial to the customer. Payment for order flow demonstrates that the order has value. The party directly responsible for that value is the customer. Yet, I would bet that most customers would be shocked to learn that their broker-dealer is receiving a payment for delivering that order to a given exchange. It seems anamolous that the broker receive value for the customer's order. (Perhaps if payment for order flow is allowed to continue, the customer should receive the financial credit; this would ameliorate the potential conflict.) Specialist guaranties. Briefly, I believe these work to the long term detriment of the efficiency of the market. They enhance the benefits of scale, which, in turn, over time lead to potential greater market maker concentration, rather than the efficiency which is favored by diverse market participants. In addition, I do not understand why a larger market maker needs an inducement to carry out a function that is intrinsically profitable. If it is not profitable, they will not do it. As a note, perhaps guaranties make sense for specialists in issues with light volume as an inducement to provide a market. In that case, a volume threshold for allowing guaranties might be a reasonable requirement. Internalization. This is a conflict of interest if there ever was one. Despite attempts to sanitize the risk through preceding auctions and other structures, in the end, history suggests, smart market participants will abuse this potential conflict of interest to the customer's detriment. And, similar to payment for order flow, it is very hard to discern and prove and it distances the party bringing the value of the order, i.e. the customer, from the party receiving the value for the order. Thank you for considering my comments. Very truly yours, Bruce Mitchell