0001 1 U.S. SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION 2 3 4 5 MEETING OF 6 SEC ADVISORY COMMITTEE ON 7 SMALL AND EMERGING COMPANIES 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 Friday, September 7, 2012 16 9:00 A.M. 17 18 19 20 21 22 U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission 23 San Francisco Regional Office 24 44 Montgomery Street, Suite 2800 25 San Francisco, California 0002 1 PARTICIPANTS: 2 3 ADVISORY COMMITTEE MEMBERS: 4 STEPHEN M. GRAHAM, CO-CHAIR 5 M. CHRISTINE JACOBS, CO-CHAIR 6 DAVID A. BOCHNOWSKI 7 JOHN J. BORER, III 8 DAN CHACE 9 MILTON CHANG 10 JOSEPH (LEROY) DENNIS 11 SHANNON L. GREENE 12 RICHARD L. LEZA 13 KATHLEEN A. McGOWAN 14 CATHERINE V. MOTT 15 KARYN SMITH 16 CHARLIE SUNDLING 17 TIMOTHY WALSH 18 19 SEC PERSONNEL: 20 KATHLEEN HANLEY 21 GERALD LAPORTE 22 LONA NALLENGARA 23 TED VENUTI 24 JENNIFER ZEPRALKA 25 0003 1 PARTICIPANTS (CONT.) 2 3 PANELISTS: 4 5 MORNING SESSION: 6 JAY RITTER, Ph.D. 7 DAVID WEILD 8 EDWARD KIM 9 10 AFTERNOON SESSION: 11 STEVEN E. BOCHNER 12 JEFF SCHWARTZ 13 ROBERT BARTLETT 14 15 STAFF PRESENTATION: 16 MARC FAGEL 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 0004 1 P R O C E E D I N G S 2 (9:00 a.m.) 3 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. Why don't we get started. 4 First of all, this is a minor administrative matter. 5 Just to make sure the video has feedback through the 6 mic, just make sure that the iPhones, BlackBerrys, etc., 7 are, if not back in your pocket, at least away from the 8 mic. 9 Is someone taking attendance? 10 Do we have a quorum? 11 MR. LAPORTE: Yes, yeah, we have a quorum. 12 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. Good. 13 Well, thank you everyone for coming. Once 14 again, I thank the committee members for giving us their 15 time and helping to address the issues that we've been 16 assembled to address. And as always, we appreciate 17 greatly all the work of the SEC staff. I think the 18 thing I appreciate most, based on the West Coast, is 19 we're meeting on the West Coast. This is something I 20 could definitely get used to. 21 As we all know, the charge of this committee 22 is to do -- to make recommendations to the SEC for 23 changes that will improve access to capital for smaller 24 businesses who -- related to that is of course the 25 compliance cost/benefit, which involve the burden of 0005 1 time and capital. 2 We have made a number of recommendations, as 3 you know, since we've been at this for the past -- I 4 guess about a year. 5 MS. JACOBS: I think so. 6 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. And as you know, many of 7 those recommendations showed up in the JOBS Act, and I think 8 we have made -- made some progress down the road of 9 improving access to capital for businesses. But 10 there's -- obviously, there's still a lot of work. 11 And the next areas we wanted to tackle as a 12 Committee, which was touched on in the last Committee 13 meeting, are the areas of market structure and also the 14 area of compliance. 15 In terms of market structure, the notion is 16 that there are certain -- when we think about -- when we 17 think about the demise of the small IPO, and try to, you 18 know, understand why this has occurred, certainly we can 19 understand the effects of this having occurred, but to 20 really kind of understand the causes and gain a greater 21 appreciation for perhaps what can be done in order to 22 correct the situation, if you will. 23 There are obviously differing points of view. 24 There's lots of room for debate. Certainly one of the 25 things that I think we're all aware of, the discussion 0006 1 around the, you know, so-called tick sizes, that is -- 2 that is -- we're going to spend our time this morning 3 discussing. 4 And to assist us with that discussion, we have 5 put together an expert panel. And if you don't -- if 6 you bear with me, then I'd just like to read who's 7 speaking. 8 First of all, Jay Ritter. 9 Jay, thanks for coming. 10 Jay is the Joseph Cordell Eminent Scholar in 11 the Department of Finance at the University of Florida. 12 He holds a Ph.D. in Economics and Finance from the 13 University of Chicago and has previously taught at the 14 Wharton School, the University of Michigan, University 15 of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, and MIT Sloan School of 16 Management. He is known best for his articles on 17 financial issues. 18 Thank you, Jay. 19 Dave Weild is probably familiar to most of 20 you. David has written extensively in the area of tick 21 sizes and structural changes that occurred in the market 22 over the last number of years that led to a number of 23 regulations that have perhaps unintended consequences. 24 And he was in our last -- in our last meeting. I think 25 you're familiar with his work. I don't think anybody 0007 1 knows about this area better than David. You can have a 2 different point of view, but one thing for sure is that 3 David knows his stuff. 4 He oversees Capital Markets and Institutional 5 Acceptance at Grant Thornton. He's also Chairman and 6 CEO of Capital Markets Advisory Partners, the firm that 7 specializes in equity capital markets advice to issuers. 8 He is a former Vice Chairman and Executive Committee 9 member of the NASDAQ Stock Market. And prior to NASDAQ, 10 David worked at Prudential Securities in senior 11 management roles. 12 Thank you again, David, for joining us. 13 This time, David brought one of his partners, 14 and that is Edward Kim, who is Co-Founder and Managing 15 Director of Capital Markets Advisory Partners and is 16 also a senior member of the Capital Markets group at 17 Grant Thornton. Ed has over 20 years of capital 18 markets, finance, and operations experience. 19 Again, David and Ed have produced a series of 20 studies that have been influential in the debate over 21 whether the structural and regulatory changes to the 22 stock markets have undermined capital formation in the 23 U.S. 24 Those will be our speakers this morning. They 25 will impart some of their knowledge to us. And the idea 0008 1 is that not only will they make presentations, but they 2 will be part of the conversation. And so we would 3 expect members to join in with questions and comments in 4 part of the conversation. 5 The idea today is that, you know, after we 6 hear from this morning's panel, we will break, and then 7 we'll spend a little bit of time on just kind of a JOBS 8 Act update recap. 9 We will then break for lunch, and then we will 10 hear from the panel that is going to address compliance 11 and some of the regulatory burdens that the smaller 12 companies face. We will talk about those this 13 afternoon. 14 After we hear from that panel, we will break 15 and then take time to discuss what we've heard in the 16 process following the recommendations to the SEC in 17 these areas and, you know, anything else that you want 18 to add. 19 Flipping back, the SEC staff with us today 20 are: Lona Nallengara; Gerry Laporte; Jennifer Zepralka; 21 Kathleen Hanley, and -- who is the Deputy Director and 22 Deputy Chief Economist, Division of Risk, Strategy, and 23 Innovation; and Ted Venuti, who is over in the corner, 24 who is Senior Special Counsel in the division of Trading 25 and Markets. 0009 1 And again, we thank the staff for all the work 2 that they do to support this Committee, and certainly 3 all the work they do on that basis. For those of us 4 close to the SEC, we understand -- at least we have -- 5 can't say understand, but at least we have some sense of 6 the pressure and the burdens and workload that you guys 7 face, and we thank you for that. 8 Chris, do you have anything to add? 9 MS. JACOBS: No. You covered it, I think. 10 MR. GRAHAM: Without further ado -- Mr. 11 Nallengara, do you have anything? 12 MR. NALLENGARA: No. Steve, we're going to 13 start with a brief update on -- I'm not sure if we sent 14 with the materials -- the report the SEC staff prepared 15 on decimalization on tick size. Kathleen -- 16 MR. GRAHAM: Can I stop you? 17 MR. NALLENGARA: Sure. 18 MR. GRAHAM: I hate to kind of interrupt 19 somebody's flow of thought. 20 MR. NALLENGARA: Go ahead. 21 MR. GRAHAM: Apparently the audio feed is not 22 very good for us. And so everyone who is speaking, 23 speak into the mic. 24 MS. NALLENGARA: Okay. So as I mentioned, we 25 had -- the JOBS Act required that the SEC to do a report 0010 1 within 90 days of the enactment of the JOBS Act, which 2 was July 4th, on -- on the effects of tick size and 3 decimalization on IPOs. 4 So the staff prepared this report. Kathleen 5 led our efforts on that, and that report was posted on 6 our website a few days -- weeks after the deadline, but 7 it is complete, and Kathleen is going to give us a brief 8 update on that. 9 And we turn it over to you. 10 MS. HANLEY: Thank you. 11 So as Lona mentioned, we had 90 days to do a 12 study. We took a three-prong approach to doing the 13 study. The study was mandated to look at the effect of 14 decimalization on IPOs and specifically on small- and 15 mid-cap companies. Given the tight deadline, we 16 concentrated our efforts at looking at the academic 17 literature to begin with. And then we had our 18 roundtable here where David spoke and Professor Harris 19 spoke, and we looked at international tick sizes. 20 For the most part, the studies that we were 21 able to find talked mostly about the effect of 22 decimalization around the time of decimalization on 23 market quality, things like spreads, depth, and that 24 sort of thing. 25 We did not find any studies that purported to 0011 1 speak to the link between decimalization and capital 2 formation. And I'll return to that in a moment. 3 For the most part, the effect of 4 decimalization at the time it was enacted appeared to 5 improve market quality for large liquid stocks the most. 6 We have one study that focused on small and 7 mid cap stocks, but there was no statistically 8 significant change in spreads at the time the 9 decimalization occurred. 10 I leave it to you to see the rest of the 11 findings. 12 Overall, market quality improved, particularly 13 for large stocks. Many did not make a distinction 14 between large and small stocks, and where they did, we 15 noted that. 16 But there are some caveats with using this 17 literature to draw strong conclusions about the effect 18 of tick sizes on capital formation. 19 First of all, the studies were done around the 20 time of enactment. And of course many, many years have 21 passed since then, and the markets have changed 22 substantially, the market for capital has changed 23 substantially, and these studies could not speak to 24 that. 25 In addition, the samples, many of these did 0012 1 not focus on small companies. And I don't think the 2 concerns were there at the time that the studies were 3 done. They were looking to see market quality issues. 4 So, you know, we're very cautious about saying 5 that the academic literature should drive us in any 6 direction with respect to what we should be doing or 7 what the Commission should be doing with respect to tick 8 sizes. 9 We did survey internationally. The U.S. has a 10 one-size-fits-all policy as compared to a number of 11 international venues, such as Hong Kong and Japan and 12 the UK, which have sometimes quite elaborate tick size 13 schemes, to the point where sometimes we had to spend 14 some time to figure out what tick would apply to what 15 type of company. So we are mindful that other 16 regulators and other exchanges have noticed that tick 17 size may be important for smaller companies. Generally 18 tick sizes increased with the -- with the -- with the 19 price, the company went lower. 20 And so given the discussion, we were mindful 21 that some of the direct linkages between changing tick 22 sizes and capital formation appeared to be not well 23 documented, and we wanted in the study to tee up having 24 a roundtable that would allow us to address a number of 25 questions. 0013 1 And I think there are three primary challenges 2 that I think we face when they think about this issue, 3 and I think this group may be well-suited to begin the 4 discussion of these types of challenges. 5 So the first thing is it's uncertain whether 6 or not increasing the tick size would in fact increase 7 spreads. So that would be the first. Spreads, and 8 obviously when Gregg Berman was here last time, we 9 noted that tick sizes are not spread sizes. They're 10 price movements. And so, therefore, would tick sizes 11 increase spreads? So that's the first thing. 12 And if they did increase spreads, would that 13 increase market maker profitability, or would investors 14 who benefit from lower transaction costs not transact as 15 frequently in smaller public companies? 16 So would there be an offsetting effect from 17 investors who now have to pay potentially a larger 18 spread to transact? 19 Third, if in fact investors did not take that 20 into consideration, it did not have an offsetting effect to 21 the size of spread, would market makers indeed use the 22 extra profits they have on spreads to use that money to 23 aid companies in analyst coverage and other things that 24 capital formation might benefit? 25 And so we're convening the roundtable sometime 0014 1 in the next few months, and we hope that in addition to 2 this we would have some answers to that question. 3 Also, some guidelines on how to find direct 4 causality between changing tick sizes and capital 5 formation is that it seems to be a road that has a 6 number of different paths that could occur, as well as a 7 number of different circles that, you know, one can 8 travel around to get to that point. There's analyst 9 coverage we're trying to fix. And I'm sure the 10 panelists here will have a nice viewpoint with respect 11 to that. So we're looking forward to having that, 12 whether or not we should do a pilot study, how that 13 pilot study should be conducted. 14 So we're convening a roundtable, and you 15 should be hearing more about that in the future. If you 16 have any questions about, I'm happy to answer questions 17 about that today. 18 (No audible response.) 19 MS. HANLEY: No? 20 I'll turn it over to Jay. 21 DR. RITTER: Thank you. 22 Feel free to interrupt with questions at this 23 time. Feel free to interrupt with questions or comments 24 as we go along here. 25 My presentation is going to be loosely based 0015 1 upon a working paper that I have with two co-authors, 2 Xiaohui Gao and Zhongyan Zhu, both who are educators in 3 the United States, but now teach in Hong Kong, although 4 actually, Xiaohui Gao is visiting at the University of 5 Maryland this year. 6 And the question that we're addressing here is 7 the question that is of interest to all of us: Where 8 have all the IPOs gone? 9 I believe at the June meeting Professor Jeff 10 Harris showed this -- this graph or a very similar graph 11 where this shows the annual volume of operating 12 companies in the United States from 1980 to 2011. And 13 what we see here is that from 1980 to 2000 on average 14 302 companies went public every year -- I'm sorry, 311 15 companies went public every year in the United States. 16 And in the last 11 years, which I'll call the last 17 decade for convenience, only 99 companies on average 18 have gone public. And this drop-off is even more 19 dramatic if we think about during the last three decades 20 U.S. real GDP has doubled, more than doubled. And so if 21 you think there ought to be the same number of IPOs per 22 trillion dollars of GDP, we ought to see a doubling from 23 the beginning to the end rather than this big drop-off. 24 And as we're all aware, over the last decade 25 there have been some bear markets, but the market has 0016 1 recovered, and we haven't seen a recovery in IPO volume 2 to anywhere near the levels of a normal year in the 3 1990s. 4 And even more dramatically, this big drop-off 5 has been concentrated among small company IPOs. This 6 graph defines big and small companies, not on the basis 7 of the proceeds raised or the market cap of the 8 offering, but the annual inflation adjusted sales of the 9 company in the year before going public using $50 10 million as a cutoff, where approximately half of all the 11 companies that have gone public in the last 32 years 12 were below $50 million and half above that. 13 And what you see, the red lines in back, the 14 red bars give the annual volume of large company IPOs. 15 The blue lines in front give the annual volume of small 16 company IPOs. And before 2000, from 1980 to 2000, a 17 typical year at least as many small companies went 18 public as big companies. Since then, the number of 19 small companies has been dramatically lower. And the 20 drop-off from an average year in the previous couple of 21 decades to this decade has been about 80 percent for the 22 number of small companies going public, you know. 23 So this is what we're all worried about. A 24 lot of public policy discussions focus on this. The 25 JOBS Act was certainly motivated by part of this 0017 1 pattern. 2 And as we can see here as well, even when the 3 stock market was closer to its peaks in 2007, and now 4 there has not been anywhere near the number of small 5 company IPOs as was typical in the 1980s and '90s. 6 If we look at the age distribution of 7 companies going public, this is each year, the 25th, 8 50th, and 75th percentile of the age since founding of 9 companies going public, what you see is in the '80s and 10 '90s, most years the median age was about seven or eight 11 years. That dropped a bit during the Internet bubble 12 period. But in the last decade very few young companies 13 have been going public. So whether we focus on sales or 14 the age of companies going public, young small companies 15 just have not been going public this decade. 16 That doesn't mean that there aren't any young 17 small companies out there. The venture capitalists have 18 poured a lot of money into financing small companies, 19 merging companies in the last decade. There's a big 20 increase in the amount of VC funds committed in '99 and 21 2000. And if you would think more money being poured 22 into venture capital ought to lead five years later to 23 more IPOs, we would have expected to see more IPOs this 24 decade rather than fewer. 25 This graph shows from 1990 to 2011 of the 0018 1 exits of venture capitalists, so in other words, of 2 their portfolio companies that they're exiting either by 3 a trade sale or by taking the company public. 4 The green part of the bars are the exits via 5 going public, and the lower black parts are the 6 percentage of exits via having a company acquired, 7 merger and acquisition, a trade sale. And what you can 8 see there is in the 1990s a steady upward trend, and 9 then this decade, very few exits via IPOs, much larger 10 fraction of exits via trade sales. 11 And one big question is: For the lack of 12 IPOs, is it because the IPO market is broken, or is it 13 because of some other factor that's made trade sales 14 more attractive, or more likely some combination of 15 these things? I don't think there is one simple 16 explanation to describe all of these patterns together. 17 Well, the conventional wisdom is that the IPO 18 market is broken, and we're all familiar with a lot of 19 the arguments. 20 The Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 imposed costs on 21 publicly traded companies, especially burdensome for 22 small companies, although some of the burdensome 23 requirements were relaxed in 2007. And the JOBS Act 24 also further relaxes some of these things. 25 And as David Weild and Ed Kim will be talking 0019 1 about decimalization, Regulation FD in 2000, the Global 2 Settlement in 2003, various other things, both from 3 regulation and changes in market practice, have resulted 4 in a drop in analyst coverage, in particular, of small 5 companies. And if we make the assumption that analyst 6 coverage results in more investor interest, a greater 7 willingness of companies to pay -- a greater willingness 8 of investors to pay out a bigger price for your company. 9 The lack of analyst coverage has depressed the prices of 10 publicly traded small companies and, therefore, changed 11 the relevant price in private markets to public markets 12 and made it less attractive for a company to go public. 13 We call these explanations in our paper the 14 regulatory overreach hypothesis to over-simplify that 15 heavy-handed regulation, and some unintended 16 consequences of some of that regulation has resulted in 17 it being more expensive to be a publicly traded company, 18 and the valuation that a company can get in public 19 markets has decreased to the detriment of capital 20 formation. 21 Life is full of trade-offs, and, you know, in 22 terms of attempting to protect investors from fraud, 23 possibly some regulatory changes have gone too far. And 24 the benefits of reduced investor fraud have been more 25 than offset by excessive compliance costs, regulatory 0020 1 costs, etc. 2 I'm glad I'm not a regulator who has to get 3 these balances exactly right to trade off investor 4 protection and capital formation. I don't want to 5 pretend that the answers are always easy or how to get 6 the balances right. 7 MR. WALSH: Professor. 8 DR. RITTER: Yes. 9 MR. WALSH: Would you repeat what you said 10 about the benefits? 11 DR. RITTER: The benefits of compliance and 12 investor protection. One way to think about it is, 13 instead of stocks, what if we're talking about going 14 into a produce store and buying apples? And there's a 15 barrel of apples, a hundred apples in the barrel. And 16 from experience, we know that two of them are probably 17 rotten inside and 98 percent of those apples are going 18 to be nice and tasty. 19 Well, if we were willing to pay a dollar for a 20 good apple, we would be willing to pay 98 cents for a 98 21 percent chance that we're going to get a good apple. 22 Now, if for a penny of compliance cost the 23 store provider or we could screen out all of the bad 24 apples and figure out inside is it a good apple or a bad 25 apple and for a penny get rid of the two bad apples, 0021 1 that then there would be 98 good apples in that barrel, 2 and we would be willing to pay a dollar for each of 3 those good apples. 4 And in this simple example, the one penny in 5 compliance cost is worth more than the two cents in bad 6 apples that we're getting rid of. 7 On the other hand, if there's compliance cost 8 for 20 cents, I think most of us would be willing to pay 9 for a 2 percent chance of a bad apple rather than paying 10 20 cents to get rid of a 2 percent chance of a bad 11 apple. 12 So, you know, depending upon the numbers, 13 maybe it would be worthwhile to screen out the bad 14 apples, maybe it would not be. 15 And, you know, if we're talking about massive 16 frauds like WorldCom and Enron, compliance costs are 17 reasonable. Certainly some investor protection is 18 worthwhile, but clearly you can overdo it as well. 19 MR. WALSH: Great analogy. 20 DR. RITTER: In our paper we're arguing that, 21 while there may be overreaching regulation, we think 22 that an important reason for there being fewer small 23 company IPOs is that there has been a long-term 24 structural change going on, something that did not just 25 happen overnight, but basically getting big fast is more 0022 1 important than it used to be, especially for technology 2 companies, that for a variety of reasons increased speed 3 of communications, the half-life of innovation has 4 gotten shorter, speeding a product to market before too 5 long occurs, and the competition has a better product. 6 All of these have been gradually changing over time. And 7 getting big fast is more important than it used to be. 8 And consequently, for a company to grow slowly 9 organically is in some cases no longer the optimal 10 profit maximizing business strategy. That, instead, 11 getting big fast, possibly by making acquisitions, 12 possibly by getting acquired and allowing a bigger 13 organization to rapidly realize economies of scope. 14 Economies of scope refer to the concept of 15 related businesses having cost efficiencies or greater 16 revenue potential if you can combine related businesses. 17 Classic example is if you're selling ice cream 18 and refrigerated milk. Well, two separate companies 19 could have a truck going from grocery store to grocery 20 store delivering milk and another truck delivering ice 21 cream, but there are obvious efficiencies in the 22 distribution if you have one truck delivering both ice 23 cream and milk to the grocery stores. That would be an 24 example of economies of scope. 25 And because of the long-changing structural 0023 1 changes going on, we think that these economies of 2 scope in many industries have gotten bigger, and 3 increased importance of speed to market has become more 4 important as well. 5 And just to illustrate an idea with an 6 example, couple of years ago, this company Android came 7 up with some better operating system. I believe that 8 was an eight-person operation. And one of things that 9 they could have done was hire more engineers, more 10 software people, come up with some improved products and 11 maybe come out with a better smartphone three years from 12 now. 13 But what would they be competing against? 14 They wouldn't be competing against Samsung and Apple's 15 current model. They would be competing against Samsung 16 and Google's model three years from now. 17 And Android decided, rather than to go public 18 and build a hard product, they decided to sell out and 19 approach some potential buyers. 20 They approached Samsung. I heard the story in 21 Korea last December when I was there. And Samsung said: 22 Yeah, you got some pretty neat technology here, but 23 we've got 500 in-house Ph.D. engineers and scientists. 24 We don't need to buy your product; we can figure it out 25 ourselves. 0024 1 And so instead, Google bought Android. And 2 I've read that Google considers it their best 3 acquisition ever. 4 I don't think that Android didn't go public 5 because they were afraid of Sarbanes-Oxley compliance 6 cost or lack of analyst coverage. They decided to sell 7 out because they thought somebody like Google would be 8 able and willing to pay a much higher price now because 9 they could realize a lot of value, than if Android 10 stayed as an independent company and tried to build 11 itself up through organic growth. 12 So we call this the economies of scope 13 hypothesis that a lot of, in particular, tech companies 14 are selling out rather than going public, not because 15 the IPO market is broken, it's not a public company 16 versus a private company choice; it's a big company 17 versus small company choice, that getting big fast is 18 important, and very frequently merging is the way to get 19 big fast. 20 So the idea is based upon structural changes 21 in the product market that did not happen overnight. It 22 did not happen in April 2000 that resulted in before 23 then lots of IPOs, and suddenly after April of 2008 very 24 few IPOs. 25 Well, what's the evidence supporting this 0025 1 idea? Well, one thing we could do is look at the 2 profitability of small firms. 3 And this graph gives from 1980 to 2009 for 4 companies that have been publicly traded for at least 5 three years. So this is excluding recent IPOs. What 6 fraction of them in each fiscal year are reporting 7 negative earnings per share? And we divide this into 8 big companies and large firms and small firms using a 9 cutoff of $250 million in inflation adjusted sales. 10 What you see is on the bottom for large firms 11 there's been a little bit of an uptrend in the fraction 12 of companies every year reporting negative earnings. And 13 you definitely see some business cycle effects there as 14 well. 15 And then on top is the fraction of small 16 publicly traded firms that are reporting negative 17 earnings. And what you see there is in the 1980s there 18 was a big increase in the fraction reporting negative 19 earnings. And since then, a little bit of a continued 20 upswing. And in every year, small companies are much 21 likely to be profitable, more likely to be unprofitable 22 than big companies. 23 Now, part of the reason in recent years in the 24 last decade that companies have been having a greater 25 difficulty reporting positive earnings is, for instance, 0026 1 Sarbanes-Oxley compliance costs. And so what we do is 2 we say, well, what would the earnings have been if 3 companies didn't have those extra costs? And based upon 4 some estimates from SEC studies, we say, well, pretty 5 big company, what if they had $2.5 million less in 6 costs, and for a small company, what if they had 7 $650,000 less in annual costs; what fraction of them 8 would be profitable then? 9 And that's where those dotted lines come in 10 from 2002 through 2009. And what you see is the big 11 companies on the bottom. That gap between the lines, 12 it's called 1 percent, that only a small number of 13 companies that were unprofitable would have been 14 profitable if they didn't have that $2.5 million extra in 15 expenses. And for small companies, the gap is about 5 16 percent. So, you know, definitely compliance costs are 17 making it harder to be profitable. But we -- the 18 patterns would largely still be there. 19 MR. WALSH: These are earnings per share 20 negative in a year? 21 DR. RITTER: Yeah, yeah, they're fiscal year. 22 MR. WALSH: Over five percent of the companies 23 are negative in a year because they have $650,000 in 24 compliance costs? 25 DR. RITTER: Right. That if you look in 2009, 0027 1 the numbers for small companies are 60 percent 2 unprofitable, and it would be 55 percent -- in other 3 words, there are about 5 percent of companies where a 4 $650,000 change in earnings would shift them from being 5 unprofitable to profitable. 6 MS. JACOBS: Can I ask a quick question? 7 DR. RITTER: Yes. 8 MS. JACOBS: The $600,000 estimate on the 9 small companies, what was your market cap? 10 DR. RITTER: These -- there's no market cap 11 being used here. $250 million in annual sales is being 12 used as the definition of big and small companies. 13 MS. JACOBS: Yeah. I don't know how the rest 14 of the members feel, but I don't think the $600,000 is a 15 real number. 16 DR. RITTER: Now, this is the incremental 17 costs. 18 MS. JACOBS: That's right, yeah. 19 DR. RITTER: And -- 20 MS. JACOBS: It's the cost of being public, 21 and I think we as -- 22 DR. RITTER: Well, this is the change in the 23 cost of being public -- 24 MS. JACOBS: With SOX. 25 DR. RITTER: -- relative -- correct. 0028 1 MS. JACOBS: Yeah, got it. 2 QUESTION: Just a clarification, because of 3 per 404, non-accelerated filers are exempt, does this 4 account for that? 5 DR. RITTER: No, it does not. This assumes 6 that every company with less than $250 million in annual 7 sales has to pay an extra $650,000 in compliance costs as 8 a result of Sarbanes-Oxley. So for a company, 9 especially those exempt or since 2007, this might be an 10 overestimate. 11 You know, there's a lot of evidence that the 12 first year or two, when auditing firms were billing lots 13 of stuff, that those numbers were bigger than they have 14 been since then. And obviously for a biotech company 15 with zero sales, the numbers are likely to be smaller 16 than for another company that's got really complicated 17 revenue and all sorts of complicated accounting. 18 Okay. Another question is: Of companies that 19 are public, have a lot been going private? And this 20 graph shows, of companies that went public, how many of 21 them then went private within three years? Not getting 22 acquired by a bigger company, but going private. 23 And what you see here is most years the number 24 is about 1 or 2 percent per year. So of the companies 25 that go public this year, we could anticipate that 1 or 0029 1 2 percent of them within the next three years will 2 decide, we made a mistake, we're going private. 3 Being bought out by a private equity firm, for 4 instance, would be going private. Going dark, going 5 private. Being bought and acquired by a bigger company, 6 we don't count that as being private. So this is not 7 the big firm versus small firm issue; this is the 8 private firm versus public firm issue. 9 Most importantly, this decade there has been 10 no increase in the probability of going private than 11 there used to be. So there doesn't -- you know, it 12 seems to be something where a small number of companies 13 that went public decided within a couple of years it was 14 a mistake, but it doesn't seem to have changed much over 15 time. 16 Now, before, we were looking at companies that 17 were public for at least three years, what fraction are 18 reporting negative earnings. These are companies that 19 went public, and within three years of going public, how 20 profitable are they. 21 So, for instance, in 1980 the numbers that are 22 graphed there are for the companies for fiscal year 23 1980. Of the companies that went public in '77, '78, 24 '79 that are reporting in 1980, what fraction of them 25 are reporting negative earnings? 0030 1 And what you can see here is for the small 2 firm IPOs the same uptrend for big -- for IPOs a little 3 bit of an uptrend. But just as we saw it in the other 4 graph, small companies are much more likely to report 5 negative earnings than big companies. 6 And note that April of 2000 is nothing special 7 here. It's not as if suddenly there was this dramatic 8 change when the tech stock boom collapsed or when 9 Sarbanes-Oxley came in or anything else. You know, 10 we've got a gradual trend going on consistent with the 11 notion that there have been some long-term trends going 12 on making it harder and harder for small independent 13 companies to make money. 14 Now, this is just tech stocks or just biotech 15 stocks. A lot of numbers here. Not going to ask you to 16 memorize all these numbers. The effects are a little 17 stronger for tech stocks than for other industries. But 18 the patterns are there for other industries as well, and 19 the patterns are stronger for small companies than big 20 companies. 21 MR. DENNIS: Professor, going back to your 22 graph, it showed something like 60 percent of small 23 companies are losing money? 24 DR. RITTER: Yeah. And here, for small IPOs, 25 you see it's over 70 percent. 0031 1 MR. DENNIS: Okay. Well, yeah, I was looking 2 at the earlier one: 3 DR. RITTER: Yeah. 4 MR. DENNIS: So you're saying that's not -- 5 you know, when I look at the original bubble back in the 6 '90s or so -- yeah, in that one. Let's see. Where it 7 went from 20 to about 45 percent or so. 8 DR. RITTER: Yeah, in the 1980s. 9 MR. DENNIS: In the '80s, '90s. Now, my 10 assumption without any fact is that that's more a high 11 tech or start-up that. Are you telling me there's 12 really not much difference? If we graph this for plain 13 old manufacturing companies that we would see the same 14 kind of relationship? 15 DR. RITTER: Yeah. Indeed, go to the numbers 16 for Panel C would be the plain old manufacturing 17 companies and retailers and others, fast food chains. 18 We see that for the small companies in 1980 to 2000, 49 19 percent of those nontech companies were reporting 20 negative earnings. The last decade has been typically 21 90 percent. So it increased, not as dramatic as the 22 deterioration and profitability of tech firms, but the 23 pattern is still there for other industries as well. 24 What about being acquired? This graph gives 25 for IPOs what's the probability of being acquired within 0032 1 three years of going public? 2 And the orange lines give large firms; the 3 blue bars give small companies. Once again, $50 million 4 in pre-IPO annual sales being the definition of small 5 versus large companies. 6 And we see a bit of an uptrend, especially in 7 the 1990s, for those blue bars, that in the 1990s there 8 was a pronounced trend, where in the early '90s very few 9 companies that went public got acquired within three 10 years. By the end of the '90s, a very large percentage 11 of companies that went public got acquired within three 12 years. 13 So the pattern of more likely to be getting 14 acquired was there before the tech stock bubble burst 15 and the low volume of IPOs that we see in this decade. 16 Everything we've looked at has been from the 17 United States. What about other countries? 18 Here's for Germany. See 32 years, as the 19 United States. The bars are the annual number of IPOs 20 in Germany, one of the world's largest economies. The 21 connected lines on the left-hand axis are the average 22 for the returns on IPOs. And what we see there is a 23 very different scale than the United States. 24 In most years in Germany, if we look at the 25 1980s, typically only 10 or 20 companies went public in 0033 1 Germany. They did not have Silicon Valley. They still 2 don't. In the late '90s they had a bit of a tech stock 3 boom, but it hasn't been there this decade either. 4 And if we look at other continental European 5 countries, the patterns are very similar to Germany. 6 If we look at China, of course it's a 7 different pattern. Lots of state-owned companies have 8 been going public in recent years. 9 What about the returns earned by investors? 10 At the June meeting I believe Professor Jeff 11 Harris gave some numbers from my website. These are 12 obviously perfectly correlated with the numbers that he 13 presented. 14 On the left-hand side here, we see for small 15 company IPOs. From 1980 to 2000, the gray bar gives the 16 three-year buy-and-hold return from the first date 17 closing price to three years later, how much did 18 investors earn. And what you can see there, an average 19 three-year buy-and-hold return of about 7 percent, 20 annualized only about 2 percent per year as small 21 company IPOs. Whereas if you had bought other small 22 companies on the same day as the IPO, sold them on the 23 same day, you would have gotten that red bar, about 20 24 percent buy-and-hold returns. In other words, small 25 companies underperform. 0034 1 What about the last decade? From 2001 to 2 2009, the difference in returns has been even more 3 dramatic. You would have actually earned negative 4 average returns on the small company IPOs, whereas you 5 would have earned positive returns on investing in other 6 publicly-traded small company stocks. 7 On the left-hand side, we've got large firm 8 IPOs where there's basically no difference between the 9 gray and red bars. For larger companies going public, 10 they don't underperform other similar kind of companies 11 either in the '80s or '90s or in this decade. 12 And if I were to break this out in more 13 detail, in the 1980s, the small company IPOs 14 underperformed; in the 1990s, they underperformed; in 15 the bubble years, they underperformed; in this decade, 16 they've underperformed. One of the few patterns that 17 has been reliable, just period after period. 18 And, you know, maybe one of the reasons that 19 investors are willing to pay as much for small company 20 IPOs is they've learned, you know, after decade after 21 decade of having so few of the companies become 22 profitable and earn big returns for investors, they just 23 had kind of a buyers strike. But it's not because 24 investors are irrational; it's because the companies 25 just haven't been turning the corner and becoming 0035 1 profitable frequently enough. 2 MR. CHACE: The $50 million is the threshold 3 that you used, right, for small companies? 4 DR. RITTER: Yes. 5 MR. CHACE: If you break that either by 6 deciles or quartiles kind of market cap size, is the 7 relationship linear to larger? Because my perception is 8 that $50 million is a pretty small -- 9 DR. RITTER: Yeah. 10 MR. CHACE: Hard to understand for sure. 11 DR. RITTER: It's linear as you go from zero 12 up to 50. The lower the sales, the worse the returns 13 are. Once you hit that $50 million cut-off, it's pretty 14 much the returns are similar to other companies of the 15 same market cap in value versus growth characteristics. 16 MR. CHACE: So it is kind of the smallest of 17 the small. 18 DR. RITTER: Yes. Now, the reason I'm using 19 sales rather than market cap is when you use market cap, 20 you're combining both big companies like Facebook and 21 overvalued companies like Facebook. 22 And in particular, in the bubble years you had 23 a lot of really tiny companies at astronomical valuation 24 that then crashed and burned. And if I did this on the 25 basis of proceeds or market cap, the numbers would look 0036 1 even worse. 2 MR. GRAHAM: To what extent do you think the 3 lack of access to capital plays a role in small 4 companies failing to provide a better return? Talking about a 5 vicious circle in some cases here? 6 DR. RITTER: Yeah, yeah. Obviously there are 7 some companies where if they had access to capital, they 8 could have turned a corner. But I'd be -- you know, and 9 there certainly are some companies that have a viable 10 business strategy that weren't able to raise financing 11 at sufficiently attractive terms, that they never did 12 make the investment that would have turned out to be 13 good. 14 However, if we look at the realized returns 15 earned on venture capital investments over the last 16 decade, which in general has been pretty poor, I'd be 17 willing to assert that the problem is not lack of 18 capital; it's lack of good companies, lack of good 19 investment opportunities. 20 Indeed maybe even the problem has been too 21 much capital resulting in low returns for both venture 22 capitalists and public market investors. If the prices 23 that investors paid were lower, the returns would have 24 been higher. 25 Now, getting the balance right is not easy, 0037 1 you know. For companies with good prospects, they ought 2 to be able to raise money at fair terms reflecting their 3 growth prospects. And for companies that don't have 4 good investments, the market is working when the market 5 refuses to fund those companies. 6 I'd be more concerned about capital formation 7 being the fundamental problem if venture capitalists and 8 their limited partners were earning incredibly high 9 returns over the last decade. 10 I'm not going to claim that I know how to get 11 things right, that I know what the right amount of 12 capital is or what the right regulations are. But the 13 main point that I want to make is that it's been really 14 difficult for a lot of small companies, especially in 15 the technology space, to come up with viable business 16 models that earn positive profits and earn high returns 17 for their investors as freestanding independent 18 companies; that I think a major reason that a lot of 19 companies are selling out, venture capitalists are 20 exiting by selling out rather than taking their company 21 public is because the company is worth more as part of a 22 larger organization that can speed products to market, 23 integrate technology, create value, than if the company 24 was trying to grow organically. 25 MR. GRAHAM: So -- 0038 1 DR. RITTER: And there's not one business 2 model that fits all for every company. 3 MR. GRAHAM: Right, it's a complicated 4 question, and there are a lot of factors. But some 5 companies fit some model, some companies don't. 6 DR. RITTER: I agree. And, look, my focus on 7 IPOs has been for more than 30 years. I would really 8 like it to be the case there is a vibrant market for 9 IPOs in the United States and throughout the world. 10 MR. CHANG: These statistics are very 11 interesting and informative, but I'm not sure where 12 we're going with this. It's a little bit like the 13 problem with the apple analogy. If you pick that one 14 bad apple, I mean, you lost it, you lost your one buck. 15 So what does that really tell us in terms of 16 from an investor standpoint? 17 DR. RITTER: What it tells us is that 18 investors haven't been able to find enough good apples. 19 That, you know, for every eBay and Google that have 20 given investors really good returns, there just have 21 been too many companies that have been disappointments. 22 Now, you know, just like with venture capital, 23 the fact that a lot of the companies have lost money, 24 that doesn't bother me. You know, venture capitalists 25 are counting on the right skewness, enough tenbaggers to 0039 1 balance out a lot of write-offs. 2 And when you invest in young companies, even 3 if it's a public young company, a lot of them are going 4 to disappoint. If there were enough winners to offset 5 the losers, the average return would be fine. 6 But, you know, the evidence -- and I wish the 7 numbers were different than they are. The evidence 8 seems to be that there just haven't been enough 9 companies that have been able to transform their 10 business into a big successful business when they go 11 public at a very young age in their lifecycle. 12 You know, and if we think about Microsoft, 13 Google, they were already big, successful, profitable 14 companies when they went public. That -- I have 15 difficulty coming up with a lot of examples of companies 16 that went on to big success that went public at a very 17 early stage before they had demonstrated a fair amount 18 of operating success. 19 MR. LEZA: On one of the -- do you have a 20 chart? For example, there's been a lot of what I call 21 structural changes. 22 In one of them, for example, and I've never 23 seen a chart, is when you look at -- and especially if 24 you look at high technology and you look before the 25 bubble, you look at the multiples that people were being 0040 1 acquired versus the multiples from a strategy point of 2 view that are being acquired after the bubble, I mean, 3 there's a tremendous change. Before the bubble, you 4 never heard about a multiple from a corporation taking 5 7X, you know. 6 And that's a big change. And that's why a lot 7 of people, you know, they'd rather take it now than wait 8 and say, okay, let's go IPO and see what happens. 9 You ever done a multiple chart to show that? 10 DR. RITTER: I've done related things. Let's 11 give another example here. 12 Facebook. The IPO has gotten a lot of 13 criticism. It's still a great company. The only 14 problem is investors made too high a multiple. You 15 know, they built in expectations that were just too 16 optimistic. You know, I still think it's a great 17 company. I'm too old to be a user myself, but, you 18 know, they've got a business model that's working. You 19 know, maybe it's not going to be as profitable as some 20 people had hoped it would be. Only time will tell on 21 that. 22 By the way, Steve, how am I doing for time? 23 MR. GRAHAM: You're okay. 24 DR. RITTER: Okay. 25 MR. GRAHAM: I'm assuming that you're going 0041 1 for another hour. 2 DR. RITTER: I won't take it that long. 3 MR. GRAHAM: You're good. 4 MR. BORER: Question: Given your years -- 5 your years in the field and given some of these 6 statistics we've seen, given that the number of 7 transactions pertaining here down by 60 percent in IPOs, 8 the number of trade sales by venture capitalists and 9 private equity, strategic (inaudible) other companies in 10 lieu of IPOs, is part of this return driven by the fact, 11 in your opinion, that the better companies didn't IPO on 12 average, went another route, and that the market itself 13 of IPOs, given all the people involved, is not very good 14 at discriminating between what's a good opportunity and 15 a bad, and obviously over time efficiency prevails, 16 based on performance, growth, profitability, etc.? 17 DR. RITTER: You know, it's clear, you know, 18 with the benefit of hindsight in 1999, 2000, there was a 19 bubble that investors were too optimistic in paying 20 prices that were not justifiable. 21 You know, a year or two ago, lots of people 22 were asking about social media companies, are we in 23 bubble 2.0? And the answer I gave them is: I'm not 24 sure. That in '99, 2000, I had no question in my mind 25 that there was a bubble going on, just like six years 0042 1 ago I had no question in my mind that there was a real 2 estate bubble going on. 3 With social media companies like Facebook, the 4 fact that Google is now making $10 billion a year in 5 annual after-tax profits demonstrated how profitable 6 targeted search advertising can be as a business model. 7 If Google hadn't been so successful, Facebook would have 8 never gotten the valuation that it had gotten to. 9 And a year ago, even six months ago, I was not 10 at all positive that Facebook's valuation was too 11 optimistic. You know, right now, I'd probably revise 12 that answer. 13 But, you know, I don't think that it was 14 obvious that the social media frenzy gotten has too 15 completely out of whack. You know, most of the time 16 when there is a bubble, you can tell a rational story or 17 optimize. The only question is, is it too optimistic a 18 story? And it's hard to quantify when you've got a lot 19 of uncertainty about the future. 20 I'm not sure if that fully answers your 21 question, but I'm not sure that I've got a single 22 answer. 23 Okay. So let me just summarize the evidence 24 so far. Small firm IPOs have become less profitable 25 post IPO. There has been a dramatic decline in 0043 1 profitability after 2000, but that decline in 2 profitability is not limited to tech firms, and there 3 had been a trend going on for quite a while. 4 And mergers have become more common, both 5 venture capitalists selling out in a trade sale and 6 companies going public, and then merging. Either being 7 acquired or -- I haven't shown it, but other studies 8 have demonstrated that there has been an uptrend over 9 time in other companies that do go public, how many of 10 them make acquisitions themselves within a couple of 11 years. 12 You know, so all of this is consistent with 13 the notion that getting big fast, possibly via M&A 14 activity, is increasingly the popular business model. 15 Evidence is also that small firm IPOs have 16 generated disappointing returns. And the one way we can 17 summarize this is eat or be eaten. You know, that 18 getting big fast either as an acquirer or being acquired 19 is increasingly the value-maximizing business strategy, 20 not for every single business, but, you know, on 21 average, especially in the technology space. 22 Now, I'd like to spend some time talking about 23 analyst coverage and tick size, something that I and David 24 Weild and Ed Kim will be talking about further this 25 morning as well. 0044 1 In my paper, co-authored paper "Where Have All 2 the IPOs Gone?" we track down from all the companies 3 that went public from '94 to 2009 what was the analyst 4 coverage on these stocks. 5 And we find that both from '94 to 2001 on the 6 right and from 2002 to 2009 on the right, '94 to 2001 is 7 on your left, that the gray bars are small company IPOs, 8 the red bars are large company IPOs. Close to 100 9 percent of the companies that go public do get analyst 10 coverage. That was true in the '90s; it's still been 11 true now. 12 Of the handful of companies that don't get 13 analyst coverage, typically there are very small firms 14 or there's some special circumstance, or maybe the data 15 is missing the coverage that actually was there. 16 A few years ago I did a separate study where I 17 started out using a standard database, IFES, looking at 18 analyst coverage, and then looked at the companies where 19 IFES was complaining there was no analyst coverage. 20 Started going to the underwriters’ website and doing 21 Google searches and discovered that almost all the times 22 there actually was analyst coverage from the lead 23 underwriters' analyst, it's just that IFES didn't list 24 it for some reason or another. 25 Now, what this does not answer is: How many 0045 1 companies aren't going public because they couldn't find 2 an underwriter that was willing to provide analyst 3 coverage? 4 And, you know, certainly there are some 5 companies that are so small that any reputable 6 underwriter is going to say, look, the economics just 7 aren't going to work for me to have an analyst cover 8 your company. Come back with -- when you're bigger, and 9 then we can consider it. 10 But of the companies that do go public, it's 11 pretty rare that they don't have analyst coverage. And 12 usually coverage from multiple layers. 13 Now, regarding tick sizes and stock. 14 MR. WEILD: Jay. 15 DR. RITTER: Yes. 16 MR. WEILD: If I can, we've done studies on 17 research -- we didn't bring them here today. But the 18 ratio of number of research analysts to companies has 19 definitely declined over time. 20 DR. RITTER: I agree. 21 MR. WEILD: And some of the stuff in the 22 economic literature, and I'm not fresh on, that 23 basically says that you need about six research analysts 24 for stocks to trade, you know, more efficiently. 25 We think that the problem with research, 0046 1 though, is not a research problem per se, that a lot of 2 this research is sitting on the shelf collecting dust, 3 that nobody is actively marketing it to drive liquidity. 4 And so, you know, it's up there for show to make -- to 5 make the issuers feel like they're actually getting 6 something. But the actual amount of time that an 7 analyst is spending with the company is -- is -- is -- 8 can be pretty trivial. And particularly as you get into 9 smaller companies. 10 DR. RITTER: I agree with you. I'm not sure 11 that six analysts -- you know, there's no magic number. 12 The more, the better. And by the time you're up to the 13 23rd analyst, the 24th analyst isn't going to make much 14 difference. 15 Obviously the first couple of analysts are 16 more important, and having analysts that really are 17 involved, rather than just sitting there doing very 18 little, certainly makes a difference as well. 19 MR. WEILD: Yeah, I agree, yeah. 20 DR. RITTER: As Kathleen Hanley pointed out at 21 the beginning, bid-ask spreads have declined over time. 22 For small company stocks before 1994, they were 23 typically 25 cents or 50 cents; now more typically 1 to 24 10 cents, you know, sometimes larger than that. And for 25 big company stocks, you know, one penny is a very 0047 1 typical spread. 2 At the same time, depth has decreased over the 3 last two decades as well. You can't trade as many 4 shares without the price moving a little bit. 5 And the reduction in bid-ask spreads for small 6 stocks has been very good for individual investors who 7 are buying less than a thousand shares of a stock. 8 For institutional investors that want to buy 9 or sell a big block, the lack of depth has been a 10 detriment to them offsetting some of the benefits of 11 lower gross spreads. 12 This is a very simple summary of things 13 obviously in light as more complicated issues go on as 14 well. 15 Let's ask: How does a larger spread boost a 16 stock's price? You know, the logic is wide bid-ask 17 spreads are profitable for market makers. Profitable 18 market-making creates an incentive to generate trading 19 volume. Analyst coverage generates trading volume, so a 20 securities firm that makes markets in a stock -- or 21 makes a market in a stock has an incentive to have an 22 analyst cover that stock or cover stocks in general. 23 So, you know, the logic, which I completely 24 agree with, is wider bid-ask spreads don't make trading 25 more profitable, that creates an incentive for a market 0048 1 maker to have an affiliated analyst generating trade 2 volume. 3 Also, analyst coverage increases the demand to 4 own the stock and hold it as well as trade the stock. 5 MR. WALSH: Professor, how do you define 6 "securities firm"? 7 DR. RITTER: I would -- I'm thinking of that 8 in terms of an integrated securities firm that does both 9 underwriting, market-making. 10 And, you know, one of the market structure 11 changes that's been going on in the last decade in 12 particular is how specialists and market makers have 13 largely been replaced by high frequency traders. 14 MR. WALSH: Which are essentially securities 15 firms? 16 DR. RITTER: Yes, sometimes hedge funds being 17 made to high traders. But certainly there have been 18 some major structural changes there. 19 MR. WALSH: There are structural changes 20 coming down the road making it harder and harder for 21 traditional securities firms -- Goldman Sachs, Merrill 22 Lynch -- to make markets -- 23 DR. RITTER: Right, I agree with that. 24 MR. WALSH: -- getting ready for the next 25 chapter. 0049 1 DR. RITTER: And analyst coverage increases 2 the demand to own the stock, boosting the stock price. 3 While I agree with this logic, the question 4 is: Well, how big is the effect? What's the 5 quantitative effect? Well, there is some evidence out 6 there. 7 Actually, one of my colleagues, Mike Ryngaert, 8 along with one of our former doctoral students, Cem 9 Demiroglu, published an article two years ago where they 10 looked at over 500 companies that had no analyst 11 coverage where an analyst initiated coverage, typically 12 by grading, and looked at what happens to stock price 13 when the analyst started covering the stock. And they 14 found that, on average, the stock price jumped 5 15 percent. And there was no evidence that it immediately 16 decreased back down to where it had been before. And 17 almost all of these were small company stocks with a 18 market cap of less than $250 million. 19 So I think there, you know, is definitely 20 quantitative evidence out there about just how much 21 analyst coverage does affect a stock's price. 22 Now, this is a short run effect. If that 23 analyst puts out a report once and then never does 24 anything again, you know, ten years from now, I'm sure 25 the stock would have gone back down to where it would 0050 1 otherwise be. 2 If the analyst, you know, continues to 3 actively cover the stock, I would expect that the stock, 4 after going up by 5 percent, would largely stay up. 5 But, you know, in the long run what happens to 6 the stock prices is mainly dependent on the operations 7 of the company. You know, if the company fails to 8 execute, the stock prices, eventually it's going to go 9 to zero no matter how many analysts are covering it. And 10 if the company becomes incredibly profitable, the stock 11 is going to be going up no matter how many analysts 12 cover it. And more analysts will cover it, as the 13 market cap increases. So we've got some quantitative 14 measure. 15 MR. CHACE: I just have to add a little bit of 16 skepticism to that, to put it politely, but I'm kind of 17 skeptical of research, the effect of research on small 18 and micro cap firms and its value. 19 Generally, my perception is that neglected 20 stocks that get research coverage typically have 21 something positive going on. 22 And I don't know the duration of this, you 23 know, the 5 percent. It sounds like it's kind of 24 immediate. 25 But I think there's some risk. And without 0051 1 having read the study, it's a group of stocks that may 2 have some positive things going on. 3 DR. RITTER: You're raising a very good point. 4 In one respect this might be an upper-bound estimate and 5 potential overestimate in terms of -- you know, if I'm 6 an analyst and I'm looking at some companies that are 7 currently uncovered, and I'm thinking, you know, should 8 I initiate coverage on this, when I start doing my due 9 diligence investigation, if I decide, you know, this 10 company's prospects aren't all that good, my incentive 11 is almost certainly -- I'm not going to bother covering 12 this. 13 Whereas if I decide, hey, yeah, this company 14 has really got some good things going on, but the market 15 hasn't discovered yet, I'm much more likely to decide to 16 initiate coverage. 17 And so what's going on when I announce I'm 18 covering the stock is I'm also telling the market about 19 some good things that would have been eventually 20 presumably coming out anyway. But I'm just kind of 21 moving up the date at which the market finds out about 22 the good news. 23 So indeed, it is difficult to disentangle kind 24 of the information from the coverage itself. And it's 25 very plausible to think, as you are, that we've got two 0052 1 effects going on that are compounded into this one 2 number. And so 5 percent would be an overestimate. 3 It also depends on who the analyst is. If 4 it's an analyst at Goldman Sachs who has got a lot of 5 credibility already, there's likely to be a much bigger 6 effect. If it's a no-name analyst at a regional 7 brokerage firm, that hasn't got very good following. 8 MR. WALSH: There's also other kinds. The 9 product firm that look to buy these things, hedge funds. 10 Just because someone is an analyst doesn't mean they're 11 the only expert. 12 DR. RITTER: Right. This is restricted to 13 sell-side analysts from securities firms. 14 And there are a variety of reasons to treat 15 any number with a little bit of a grain of salt and 16 think about what else is going on as well. 17 You know, we've got some trade-offs. Wider 18 bid-ask spreads increase the cost of trading, which, 19 everything else the same, ought to result in lower 20 liquidity and a lower stock price. So we've got this 21 benefit to the company of a wider bid-ask spread 22 encouraging their analyst coverage, but we've got a 23 negative to the company of a wider bid-ask spread to 24 make the stock much liquid. 25 And empirically, which effect is going to 0053 1 dominate? Well, partly it depends on how much bang for 2 the buck do you get with more analyst coverage from a 3 wider bid-ask spread. Is 5 cents the right bid-ask 4 spread? Is 25 cents? Is $2? 5 Obviously too wide of a bid-ask spread is 6 going to have such a negative effect on trading that the 7 benefits to the company are going to be more than offset 8 by that bid-ask spread that's too wide. 9 And I'm not sure exactly how to balance this, 10 but obviously I'm quantifying what effects would be 11 needed on what the right ticks would be. 12 Now, as I indicated before, how lower bid-ask 13 spreads benefitted small traders, wider bid-ask spreads 14 are a tax on small traders. If you think about this as 15 a tax, why have an implicit tax of, let's say, as a 16 bid-ask spread moves from a penny to 5 cents, well, 17 that's a tax of 4 cents per share on a trade. Why do it 18 in a disguised manner rather than just have a tax, you 19 know, an explicit tax of 4 cents per share with a 1 cent 20 bid-ask spread? 21 And the tax revenue could be paid directly to 22 the analyst. So rather than having all these indirect 23 effects, if the goal is to have more analyst coverage, 24 why not do it in the most efficient way possible of, you 25 know, raising money to pay the analysts directly? 0054 1 That then raises the question: Who should be 2 taxed? Should we be taxing traders, or should you tax 3 the company? You know, should a company pay $100,000 a 4 year to pay analysts to cover the stock? 5 Well, a couple of years ago I was part of a 6 NASDAQ/Reuters joint venture designed to get analyst 7 coverage for uncovered small company stocks called the 8 Independent Research Network, where this joint venture 9 went out and talked to companies and proposed, look, for 10 $120,000 a year, you pay us, the middleman, to go out 11 and hire three independent analysts. 12 There's an obvious conflict of interest if you 13 pay the analyst directly, you know, because everybody 14 knows you're only going to be paying for an analyst if 15 it's by recommendation and that analyst is going to have 16 a lot of credibility. 17 But the NASDAQ/Reuters joint venture idea was: 18 We'll be the middleman. And in return for you making a 19 three-year commitment for analyst coverage, we will go 20 out and hire three independent analysts who agree to 21 cover your company for three years. And part of the 22 deal is, even if that analyst puts out a buy 23 recommendation, we still have to talk to the analyst. 24 You know, we want there to be independence, so that in 25 fact this analyst has credibility. 0055 1 And the idea is that this was not going to be 2 enough money, you know, subsidy of maybe $25,000 per 3 analyst per year to fully incentivize an analyst to 4 cover a company where the analyst wouldn't. But if the 5 analyst also generated some more trading volume and got 6 soft dollars, you know, there would be additional 7 sources of revenue for the analyst as well, but this 8 would result in more analyst coverage for companies that 9 were uncovered. 10 And what this joint venture found out when 11 they went out and started marketing the idea to 12 companies is there just weren't many companies willing 13 to pay $120,000 a year. 14 So let me just wrap up. 15 You know, we've talked about a problem with 16 declining profitability for small companies. I just 17 talked about tick size to analyst coverage a bit. There 18 are other possible explanations why there have been 19 fewer small company IPOs that I'm sure you discussed 20 already: the demise of Four Horsemen, fewer securities 21 firms that can kind of focus on small companies, 22 depressed stock market over the last decade. 23 But on the other hand today, both the level of 24 NASDAQ and the S&P 500 are way above what they were in 25 1996. And there are a lot more small company IPOs in 0056 1 1996 than there are today. 2 The litigation environment certainly doesn't 3 make it attractive to become a public company, but I'm 4 not sure the litigation environment today is worse than 5 it was 15 years ago. 6 Patent trolls are a problem for companies. 7 But whether you're private or public, patent trolls are 8 a problem. 9 So what about the policy -- 10 MR. WALSH: What is a "patent troll"? 11 DR. RITTER: A patent troll would be a company 12 or lawyers that buy out patents and then sue people, sue 13 people for patent infringement. Basically they're 14 trying to make their money from lawsuit settlements and 15 royalties from owning the patents rather than creating 16 value for society themselves. 17 So what are some of the policy implications? 18 Well, the stock exchanges and some elements of the VC 19 industry argue that structural changes, like subsidizing 20 analyst coverage, lowering regulatory burdens, are 21 needed to boost IPO activity. 22 And I'm sympathetic to these ideas. I think 23 they would boost IPO activity, but my guess is 24 quantitatively they're only going to boost IPO activity 25 by a very tiny amount, that I think the main thing going 0057 1 on is some of these bigger structural changes that the 2 fundamental problem is getting big fast is increasingly 3 the profit (inaudible) business model. It's not a 4 private versus public market issue; it's a big company 5 versus small company issue. 6 So thank you for your thoughts and -- 7 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. Thank you. 8 DR. RITTER: -- I'll be here the rest of the 9 day as well. 10 MR. GRAHAM: Thank you. 11 Why don't we keep going and -- are you up for 12 your presentation, David, or would people still like to 13 take a break? 14 MS. HANLEY: Five minutes? 15 MR. GRAHAM: Five minutes? Okay. Five-minute 16 break and we'll reconvene. 17 (A brief recess was taken.) 18 MR. GRAHAM: So we're about to hear from David 19 and Ed. If we could all take our seats. 20 Okay. David and Edward, it's all yours. 21 MR. WEILD: Terrific. 22 Well, first, on behalf of Ed and myself, I'd 23 like to just say thank you for inviting us back again. 24 And any time that you can do something that in your 25 heart of hearts you think really can materially benefit 0058 1 the U.S. economy, I think is just a very special and 2 cherished opportunity. 3 I wanted to mention, before we kind of watch a 4 couple of things about some of the data sets that we 5 were looking at, we have, I think as everybody knows who 6 saw me speak the last time, I like to say I'm a 7 practitioner with an analytical bend. And one of the 8 things that we've been able to do since we started 9 publishing, we go around the country and speak at quite 10 a number of events, to securities attorneys, we also 11 spoke at the American Bar Association, Securities 12 Regulation luncheon in Washington, D.C., the Securities 13 Regulation Institute, at sell-side conferences sometimes. 14 And we spend a lot of time with venture capitalists, 15 people that sort of share -- some of the people that are 16 on the board, the advisory -- the Venture Advisory Board 17 of Silicon Valley Bank, I was in seeing Kate Mitchell, 18 who chaired the IPO Task Force to the U.S. Treasury 19 recently. Have known sort of the last five chairmen of 20 the venture -- of the National Venture Capital 21 Association. 22 And so what I -- what I, you know, heard 23 pretty consistently over the last decade is that venture 24 capitalists don't trust the IPO markets and are building 25 companies for sale. 0059 1 And the first question out of their mouth, 2 which is very different from a decade ago, is -- or 15 3 years ago, really, is, you know: Who are the natural 4 buyers for your company? 5 And in our advisory practice, when we sit at 6 the table with CEOs and CFOs discussing about their 7 outlook, a lot of them will sit there and say: We just 8 don't trust the IPO market. I don't want to get turned 9 into a zombie stock. And these are profitable 10 companies. 11 I'll give you a case in point. BigFix, which 12 is up in Emeryville, California, just a little bit right 13 over the Bay Bridge, and is a venture-funded company. 14 And they had some volatility in their earnings. 15 Profitable company. They just said: No, can't take the 16 risk of how the market is going to treat us. If we miss 17 a number, we'll never get dug out of the ditch. We'll 18 lose our coverage, we won't get supported, we won't come 19 back, and we will end up becoming effectively a zombie 20 stock. 21 So they ended up selling to IBM for a very, 22 you know, attractive price. Probably left quite a bit 23 of money on the table. 24 But these are the kinds of decisions or 25 discussions that go on at the board level every day. 0060 1 And I think that when you look in the sample 2 set, sometimes there's a bit of adverse like -- two 3 things going on. 4 One is that companies that have to go, you 5 know, public, they don't have the alternative for being 6 forced. They're probably not the creme de la creme in 7 some instances. 8 Certainly biotechnology, because of the scale 9 amount of capital, many times has to go public, and 10 these companies are clearly, you know, needing the 11 capital markets. And I think that it's -- it's created 12 a kind of a world of dysfunction. 13 We're going to talk about economic incentive 14 as we get through it, but we think that this is 15 absolutely the critical third leg to the stool. And if 16 you don't fix the economic incentives -- we're going 17 kinda -- I'm going to rearrange the deck chairs here for 18 you in terms of how you think about spreads, because I'm 19 listening to the discussion here, and people don't think 20 about spreads appropriately. And we're going to get 21 into that. 22 Just by way of background, Ed, my partner 23 here, traded equities for Lehman Brothers 24 internationally, traded stocks on every market in the 25 1990s internationally. He was based in London. So we 0061 1 have, you know, a pretty fair sense of stock trading. 2 He is actually a material science engineer out of MIT by 3 training. And both of us actually have a little bit of 4 a science background. I started out as an molecular 5 geneticist. So we bring kind of, again, an analytical 6 bent to sort of everything that we do. 7 And we're really passionate about sort of the 8 transformative kinds of companies and investment that we 9 think will spearhead next generation economic growth, if 10 you will, the sort of creative destruction and 11 reinvention of the U.S. economy. 12 And fundamentally, we think that by -- by 13 harming the ability of the stock markets to support that 14 process, what we have is a lot of creative destruction 15 going on right now and not enough creative reinvention. 16 You have the draft of the paper which I 17 distributed. I would urge you all -- I know it's a bit 18 of a tome to read it. There's a lot of good 19 information. 20 We talked about some of the -- we respond to 21 some of the SEC discussion around the report on 22 decimalization. We also talk specifically about what a 23 lot of people are saying on tick size. Let's just say 24 that we think that there's an avalanche of opinion 25 coming in the direction that we have to increase tick 0062 1 sizes from some pretty smart people. Ed will get into 2 that; I don't want to belabor it. 3 But this is -- this study that we present I 4 think is written for sort of the layman, if you will. 5 And it's pretty much on point. And I just want to give 6 you some conceptual -- a conceptual framework to think 7 about stock markets, which is that at some point the 8 stock markets are absolutely free, the entire 9 infrastructure implodes. Okay. You need money to 10 reinvest and to support the stock market. And I think 11 that's intuitive. 12 So when is there too little money to support 13 the aggregate infrastructure and ecosystem? It's a key 14 question. 15 And these are all things about sort of 16 tipping points that we don't think about, including, for 17 example, when do you have too much indexation and too 18 many exchange traded funds where all of a sudden stock 19 prices start to detach from fundamentals? There's not 20 enough -- there's not enough money. It's more costly to 21 do fundamental research sales and trading than it is to 22 use computers. 23 And computers are information mining 24 strategies, for the most part. They're not information 25 additive. 0063 1 And if you all of a sudden get everything into 2 the information mining bucket, stock prices are almost 3 by definition going to detach from fundamental value. 4 And the ability of markets to allocate capital will be 5 destroyed. Okay. 6 Only question is, when do you reach that 7 tipping point. 8 So by the way, the paper is pretty much 9 complete -- there may be some typos, and which I 10 apologize; Mark Graff should be through proofing -- and 11 out in the public domain printed next week. The -- but 12 we thought it was important to get it in your hands. 13 Now, this is an absolutely critical chart and 14 got a lot going on. But I want to point out that it's 15 not spreads, it's not tick sizes. It's two things going 16 on here. Okay? There is a shift from a quote-driven 17 market with Reg ATS to an electronic order execution 18 market, an electronic order book market. That happens 19 in 1998 with the implementation of Reg ATS, called 20 Alternative Trading System. 21 So I'm going to give you a couple of 22 definitions. One is the idea of a quoted spread, which 23 is what Professor Ritter, you know, talked about, what 24 everybody sees, which is what is the actual spread in 25 the market. 0064 1 And the other is the notion of a bankable 2 spread, which, as a trader, is how much money can I 3 actually make. 4 And if somebody can step ahead -- we had this 5 discussion last time. If somebody can step ahead of my 6 bid for a penny, okay, then that -- even if the spread 7 is quoted at a quarter point, my bankable spread goes 8 from a quarter point down to a penny. So when you make 9 that shift from a quote-driven market to an electronic 10 order book market, okay, what happens is the bankable 11 spread, which was equivalent to the quoted spread, goes 12 down to the tick size. 13 So in 1998 -- and everybody is looking at 14 decimalization, which is in 2001 here, okay, the key 15 thing to think about in terms of the change of economic 16 incentives, the massive shift actually occurs in 1998 17 with the implementation of Reg ATS. 18 And we're going from -- we go from a quarter 19 point down to -- actually, there's two different tick 20 sizes that -- that are in bold there. One for smaller 21 cap stocks at 1/32 and one for smaller price stocks at a 22 1/32, and larger price at 1/16. This is the NASDAQ 23 market. 24 Actually, in the appendix here you have a 25 similar chart for what's going on in the New York Stock 0065 1 Exchange and on AMEX at the time. 2 And what you see is you've gone from a quarter 3 point from most stocks down to a 1/16 or a 1/32, which 4 means you lost from 75 percent to 87.5 percent of your 5 economic opportunity as a trading firm. 6 So when we used to buy stocks on the -- in the 7 old days on a -- on the trading desk, we buy 100,000 8 shares at $10, have a quarter point spread, bankable 9 spread was -- because it was quote-driven market, it was 10 a quarter point. And we could mark that stock up from 11 10 to 10 and a quarter, make 2 and a half percent, and 12 dial for dollars, get salesmen on the phone to create an 13 order flow. And that's how liquidity was created. 14 Now, all of a sudden, when you shift to an 15 electronic order book market, whatever that tick size is 16 at a 1/16 -- or a 1/32, 1/16 represents -- what is it? 17 6.25 cents? 18 MR. KIM: (Nodding.) 19 MR. WEILD: That I've gone from 25 cent 20 economic opportunity to 6.25 cents overnight, because 21 anybody can step in front of me for a 1/16 or 1/32 as 22 the case might be. 23 MR. CHACE: Can I ask a question? 24 MR. WEILD: Yeah. 25 MR. CHACE: How responsible is high frequency 0066 1 trading for that stepping-ahead dynamic that you talked 2 about versus competition from other -- 3 MR. WEILD: It's automated. I mean, you know, 4 Dan, you're -- you know, it's a great point. 5 I mean, what we've done with computers now is 6 that we have the systems that automatically play cat and 7 mouse. So if you get into the box and you trade 8 electronically now, I mean, automatically somebody is 9 stepping ahead. You put in an order at a price, you 10 know, somebody steps ahead of you for a penny. So by 11 definition, it's causing this unnatural spread 12 compression. 13 However, if you listen to others, they'll say 14 that in the micro and the nano cap stocks -- micro being 15 defined as sub $500 million and nano cap sub $10 16 million -- by the way, that's where most capital 17 formation, IPO capital formation, historically live. 18 That's the small IPO. Okay? Spreads are still pretty 19 wide. Okay? 20 The problem is nobody can bank those spreads. 21 You got the worst of both worlds. High spreads, no 22 institutional liquidity. And if you do analysis -- we 23 did this I think the last time, but you're seeing a 24 shift of asset ownership in small micro-cap stocks to 25 smaller and smaller institutional investors. It's not 0067 1 that it's not there; it's just that they don't have 2 liquidity constraints. 3 What it's saying is that liquidity is 4 declining in small and micro-cap stock, so I've got to 5 move down market. I mean, I've got to be a smaller 6 asset manager because I can -- you know, my position 7 size is a half a million dollars. I can manage 8 half-a-million-dollar chunks, but if I'm from Fidelity 9 with a half trillion dollars in assets under management, 10 I can't make that math work. It's just I have to cover 11 too many stocks to get to any real size in my portfolio. 12 MS. JACOBS: For the benefit of committee 13 members -- I am not a researcher; however, I found this 14 chart and this set of data so compelling that I went 15 back after the data was presented to us last time and I asked my 16 financing and accounting folks to go back. And the 17 first question I asked was I asked to take our share 18 price and plot it against, but then we decided against 19 your timeline here because these are transactions of $50 20 million or less. Correct? 21 MR. WEILD: Right. 22 MS. JACOBS: So we took our share price. I 23 got to thinking, no, no, no, too many extraneous things 24 would affect the share price. 25 But what about average trading volume? 0068 1 Because there's -- liquidity is the real page 2 here, 2 right? 3 MR. WEILD: Yeah. 4 MS. JACOBS: Both for investors and for the 5 public companies. 6 So I asked them to take our average trading 7 volume over that exact same chart and see what happens 8 to our daily trading volume. And we had ended up with a 9 coefficient of correlation of 0.91. 10 Now, so I don't need to show you what that 11 says, but there is a consequence to all of this that 12 affects every one of us in this room where the public 13 companies are concerned. 14 MR. WEILD: Absolutely. 15 MS. JACOBS: It was dynamic. In fact the 16 folks in the office, they couldn't believe it because we 17 had always complained about Sarbanes-Oxley, and what 18 happened to the share price and what happened to our 19 coverage. 20 Well, go look at the average trading volume 21 per day, plot it, and it's amazingly consistent with 22 what you're saying, David. 23 MR. WEILD: I mean, it's a really -- it's a 24 really thorny problem to figure out what -- you know, 25 what the causes of this are. Because what happens is -- 0069 1 you know, you got the dot-com bubble going on during the 2 period that these changes were made, and it totally 3 obfuscates what's going on in the lower end of the 4 market. 5 And, you know, guys that are -- you know, one 6 of my old friends was Dan Case, who was the head of -- 7 president of Hambrecht & Quist years ago. He died in 8 2002 of a brain tumor. Terrific guy. Steve Case's 9 brother, who ran AOL. 10 And Dan, you know, had said to me -- we had 11 taken a run at buying Hambrecht & Quist and had a long 12 discussion about it. And for a variety of reasons, the 13 time wasn't right for them to sell. 14 So I got a courtesy call when they sold to 15 J.P. Morgan. And Dan told me that a lot of people think 16 we're going to be brilliant in top-ticking the market 17 and selling it five times book. 18 But what we're really doing is we, you know, 19 believe that these order handling rules and the 20 electronic stock markets are going to make it impossible 21 for us to keep the lights on in a bad equities market. 22 The cash -- the equities business is going to become 23 unprofitable. 24 And if you actually look at the history of 25 when these rules were implemented, there were a lot of 0070 1 people that told the SEC that this was going to have a 2 devastating impact on the profitability of the cash 3 equities business, and they pretty much dismissed the 4 people at the time, those particular concerns. 5 And I think -- I think that when I look at it 6 as a practitioner, somebody who hired and fired 7 people -- and by the way, one of the things on my resume 8 is I ran back the -- the strategic planning for banking 9 research sales and trading back when you could put all 10 those together at Prudential Securities years ago. And 11 so we made the hiring and firing decisions. 12 And I can tell you that when we were looking 13 at small cap stocks after Reg ATS was put into effect, 14 that we were cutting back commitments on the 15 over-the-counter NASDAQ trading desk at the time because 16 we just -- we couldn't make the math work. 17 Okay. Simple thing. Lots of stocks in a 18 small micro-cap area are trading at 100,000 shares or 19 less a day. Okay. If you look at J.P. Morgan, their 20 average revenue per share at J.P. Morgan, this is their 21 statistics, is one and a half cents. So let's just say 22 that the revenue opportunity, earnings opportunity may 23 be a penny. 100,000 shares, that's for the entire 24 market, that's a thousand dollars' worth of profit per 25 day. Okay? 0071 1 And a lot of that's going off in machines, so 2 you maybe you're fighting for, if you've got a research 3 analyst dedicated, a couple hundred bucks. Nobody is 4 making an investment like that. 10,000 shares, you're 5 down to a hundred -- a hundred dollars' revenue 6 opportunity. Forget it. Okay? 7 So the economic opportunity here, the 8 incentive, if you will, is -- is the vast majority of 9 the problem here when you get to the dysfunction of 10 small micro cap stocks and, in turn, the IPO market. 11 With a hundred percent certainty -- and I don't want to 12 be -- I don't want to be coy. You know, I have no doubt 13 that this is what's killing the IPO market in this 14 country. 15 So it has to be fixed. And I will tell you 16 that it will be fixed. 17 MR. BORER: David, can I ask you a question? 18 You do a great job, by the way. I was trying to get my 19 mind to lay on the, you know, the development of ECNs, 20 the establishment of the SOES system, which is taking 21 money out of pocket, the settlement with the NASDAQ 22 market makers back in -- you know, 10, 12 years ago. 23 Were those all at around the same time, 24 between this '98 and '01, '02 period? Because I recall 25 generally, I was sitting on (inaudible) -- 0072 1 MR. WEILD: Right. 2 MR. BORER: -- SOES bandits (inaudible). 3 MR. WEILD: Right. 4 MR. BORER: The point here, it wasn't the 5 dealers who were stealing the money; it was a system put 6 in place so the dealer who really wasn't a brokerage 7 firm could hire a bunch of day traders, put them on a 8 NASDAQ platform directly for the trade, and then take 9 the money from -- whether it's the Knights or the 10 Goldmans or the Rothmans, etc. Is it about the same 11 point in time? 12 MR. WEILD: Well, it started -- I mean, the 13 two things that started before this was SOES -- SOES, I 14 think was -- Ed, do you remember? Was it the late '80s? 15 MR. KIM: SOES was the late '80s. 16 MR. WEILD: But it had an effect. It started 17 to undermine the profitability. Had Instinet there too. 18 Well, what happened was you still could quote, 19 and so you could still buy and manage the spread, if you 20 will. You could buy it at 10 and mark it up a quarter. 21 Okay? Because while the trades would go off within the 22 spread -- it used to drive retail crazy because they'd 23 see ticks -- you know, they'd see trades go up within 24 the spread, and they'd say, why didn't I get that price? 25 And then you'd -- but what you would be doing 0073 1 is you would be negotiating -- because all the SOES and 2 the Instinet for the most part -- Instinet was a little 3 junkier, but SOES was all 100-, 1,000-share increments, 4 whatever you had in the -- what we call the NASDAQ Level 5 III machine at the time. That was -- you would put in 6 either a hundred with -- your market size was either a 7 hundred or a thousand shares by convention. So you 8 would get picked off. The SOES bandits would bang the 9 bid, and so people would start ducking away and you 10 would see the market makers just drop in seriatim as 11 each of them were taken out by a so-called SOES bandit. 12 But you still were able to monetize or bank 13 that quarter point for the most part. People were able 14 to hold that in place. 15 And so the degradation, you're right, had -- 16 was starting. And, you know, in some respects, if you 17 look at the sub $50 million dollar tranche, which is the 18 blue there of IPOs, you know, you're seeing some 19 degradation, if you will, as a percentage, whether or 20 not that's statistically significant. But, "phoomp," it 21 drops off a cliff in 1998 when we go from a quote-driven 22 market, with SOES and Instinet in between, to all of a 23 sudden everything is electronic posting of orders. 24 So we take all of the order handling rules 25 that you've gotta -- you've gotta post your orders into 0074 1 the market, but there was no way to really handle all 2 those retail limit orders. 3 Now, all of a sudden with the ECNs coming 4 into -- into existence -- the Brutes, Ready Books, all 5 the -- all the electronic order books, boom, everything 6 is getting posted into the market in 1998, which starts 7 the degradation of that -- of that -- of that quoted 8 spread. 9 So the quoted spread becomes much less 10 important, and anybody that wants to sort of step -- 11 restart that whole business of stepping in front of -- 12 in front of -- in front of quotes, quote market's blown 13 to bits. And that's why when you -- you know, you go 14 through this, it is -- it is really that kind of shift. 15 And so, you know, very simply, there's three 16 ways to improve economics, right? 17 One is commissions. And commissions don't -- 18 we talked to a lot of institutional investors. I talked 19 to Wasatch's folks, but -- you know, trying to get a 20 sense of what works and what doesn't work. Commissions 21 are horrible for small cap growth money managers, 22 because what it does, it goes into expense ratios, and 23 Morningstar gets all over it. 24 Tick sizes are actually a pretty interesting 25 way to improve economics because it gets into the cost 0075 1 basis from an accounting standpoint much better. 2 And then you could go back to a quote-driven 3 market, but I don't think anybody is going to do that, 4 right. 5 So the only way, if you understand the 6 formula, is that bankable spread, you know, is -- you 7 know, in a quote-driven market is pretty much equivalent 8 to the quoted spread, but in an electronic order book 9 market, bankable spread is equal to minimum tick size. 10 And by definition, you have to take up tick size to 11 improve the economics. 12 So that answer the question? 13 MR. BORER: Very helpful. 14 DR. RITTER: I agree with you that wider tick 15 sizes increase the economics for securities firms 16 trading stock. You said that the lower tick sizes were 17 killing the IPO market. 18 Could you quantify how much higher stock 19 market prices would be if the bid-ask spreads were -- if 20 the tick sizes were wider? 21 Are we talking about a stock, micro-cap stocks 22 that are currently trading for $10 a share, would they 23 go to $28 a share or to $10.12 per share? 24 MR. WEILD: Well, I think it's a -- first of 25 all, the last time, Jay, we had an exhibit, which I 0076 1 don't include here, you look in the old material, about 2 what's the profitability of the $25 million IPO. And I 3 don't know if it's in this batch. It's in one of our 4 papers. 5 But what happened with this shift was that 6 the -- that you used to basically double -- as a book 7 running manager double your profit potential on an IPO 8 prior -- when we were looking at a quote-driven market. 9 And when -- 10 MR. KIM: Appendix E. 11 MR. WEILD: Is it Appendix E? Okay. 12 And then all of a sudden we went to losing 13 money to support stocks in the aftermarket on the $25 14 million IPO. And I know that math because I did this 15 for a living. Right? We -- 16 DR. RITTER: Okay. So the problem is 17 investment bankers aren't making enough money, so why 18 don't they increase the gross spread from 7 percent to 19 14 percent if they want to double the economics? 20 MR. WEILD: Well, it wouldn't -- wouldn't 21 solve the problem because every day that I have to 22 provide support in the aftermarket is a day that I lose 23 money. So you'd just be overpaying the investment 24 bankers on the front end. And, you know, what you're 25 really looking for, you really need aftermarket support. 0077 1 And another one of the great, you know, 2 misconceptions to the market is that everybody looks at 3 research as the aftermarket support proxy, right, the 4 market for aftermarket support. In point of fact, what 5 it is is a salesman making phone calls and people 6 committing capital in a liquid stock. 7 There are two types of stocks, broadly 8 defined. I mean, the market is actually in continuum. 9 One is symmetrical order book stocks where you 10 have lots of buyers offsetting sellers. It's the 11 natural state of the S&P 500. 12 And then there's asymmetrical order book 13 stocks. Big buyer, no -- no offsetting seller. Big 14 seller, no buyer. And what happens is somebody's got to 15 go out and create liquidity for the institution. 16 And so what happens is, is that you can still 17 play around in those stocks as a retail consumer, you 18 know, with a hundred thousand shares, blah, blah, blah. 19 But when you have to get a -- when you have to put up -- 20 you know, you have to put up 500,000 shares of stock and 21 acquire that kind of position over time, you know, 22 you're going to get bored with it. You're not going to 23 be able to do it. You're sitting there playing cat and 24 mouse and ultimately you flush the position. 25 And that's what institutions that are playing 0078 1 in these markets tell me they do all the time. You 2 know, they got sold on the idea, and then they can't get 3 enough to make their -- make it work. 4 And so now you have to -- as a CEO, you have to 5 figure out, can I put some kind of a shelf registration 6 or something in, or do a PIPE transaction to get them 7 started with some volume? It's a very, you know, 8 ineffective kind of, you know, as a practical matter, 9 market to bring institutional liquidity into it. 10 And what we're seeing is like -- you know, 11 my -- back to my old analogy of flesh-eating bacteria, 12 you know, you're gradually -- you're gradually from the 13 bottom up, you know, eating out this infrastructure to 14 support, and institutions are gradually saying, okay, 15 not enough liquidity, liquidity is dried up, and I'm 16 moving out of the market. 17 So the more that you start shaving ticks -- 18 and this is one of the dangers of sub-penny quotes, 19 sub-penny tick sizes, is that if you apply them to micro 20 markets, you actually then start pushing this stuff 21 higher and higher into the marketplace. You can get 22 away with it for S&P 500 stocks, but you can't get away 23 with it in the -- in the micro caps, the small caps and 24 micro caps. So -- 25 DR. RITTER: Have you answered my question? 0079 1 MR. WEILD: Well, your question is -- you 2 know, your question is where would the share prices be, 3 right? 4 And I think that -- I don't think you -- I -- 5 this is my judgment: I don't think you can answer that 6 question. Right? I mean, I don't know -- I don't -- 7 from a scientific standpoint, I don't think you can 8 answer it. 9 The fact of the matter is these stocks lose 10 their visibility. Right? And when -- the natural state 11 of most companies is they need visibility creators. 12 Okay. And companies are struggling to get visibility 13 with investors all the time. 14 Now, they're very different -- there's two 15 types -- two types of stocks from a visibility 16 standpoint. In our consulting practice we talk about 17 supply push and demand pull. 18 A demand pull stock is like a Zynga, somebody 19 that has great -- great visibility in the consumer 20 markets. It sort of creates its own demand. Facebook 21 was a case in point. And so it's not Wall Street 22 creating their demand; it's the stocks and the brands 23 created their demand. Tesla Motors. The vast majority 24 of these people are actually getting on the phone and 25 selling the story. And when you take all the visibility 0080 1 creators out of the market, Jay, you have to be hurting 2 share prices. 3 DR. RITTER: Yeah, but -- but it seemed to me 4 that there's a very simple way to quantify this. To 5 look -- you were talking before about the dichotomy 6 between the liquid stocks, you use symmetrical, 7 asymmetrical. 8 MR. WEILD: Yeah, it's an academic term. 9 DR. RITTER: Why not look at the price 10 earnings ratio of the symmetrical versus the 11 asymmetrical stock before 1994 and now? 12 Wouldn't that be a way of quantifying the 13 change in the relative outcome? 14 MR. WEILD: It could, but you have to ask the 15 question, what's in the sample set? 16 You know, good companies -- you know, 17 companies that have alternatives are saying, I'm going 18 to sell out. You lose them, you know, you lose them 19 from the sample set. 20 You know, there's a lot of guys with 21 alternatives that just throw the towel in and say, this 22 market is too dysfunctional, I can't get the thing to 23 work and I'm going. And so that's what you're hearing 24 from practitioners. 25 So I'm very -- I'm very skeptical that you can 0081 1 cut all the numbers you want, but you have to take into 2 account what people that are making these decisions 3 every day are doing. And a lot of them are just saying, 4 keep me the hell out of the market. Excuse my French. 5 So why -- why getting markets -- 6 DR. RITTER: (Inaudible.) 7 MR. GRAHAM: Let's just go -- let's just go 8 on. 9 MR. WEILD: What? Why getting markets right 10 matters. 11 You know, look, I plead guilty sometimes to 12 being a little Pollyanna-ish, but 20 percent of kids in 13 the United States are living below the poverty line, and 14 40 percent of children are -- are -- are under what 15 they -- what's defined as low -- lower income. And this 16 is from the National Center of Children and Poverty. 17 So anything that we can do that is going to 18 drive job formation -- and I pull my hair out a little 19 bit sometimes with -- with unions, because union -- 20 union members are typically not day-trading stocks. 21 And what happens is if you can drive more 22 companies into the public market and more -- more 23 volume, you're going to create greater tax revenues, 24 which is going to go into the coffers and 25 municipalities, which is going to allow us to employ 0082 1 more -- more teachers, firemen, and policemen. These 2 things are all related. 3 And when you -- there is nothing more 4 important in the United States to consumer confidence 5 than a functioning IPO market. I mean, anybody here, 6 and there's a lot of people that are old enough, 7 remember what -- there's a lot of things wrong with the 8 dot-com bubble, but it certainly gave everybody a sense 9 that there was an opportunity, and there was a lot of 10 entrepreneurial fervor. 11 And one of the things that gets lost in these 12 job creation estimates that we do is the impact on the 13 private markets, which is that you're going to invest a 14 lot more money, take a lot more private company risk in 15 this country if all of a sudden you see that the IPO 16 market works. 17 Also, it has an impact on the M&A market. And 18 I'll quote Ray Rothrock, who's the current chairman of 19 the National Venture Capital Association, who says that 20 it takes an IPO market to keep the M&A market honest. 21 So, you know, we have said, what did the JOBS 22 Act do in broad terms? 23 It did a couple of things. It lowered cost 24 for issuers, and it improved issuer communications with 25 investors. 0083 1 And we say that there is an actual, essential 2 third leg to the stool, that without that, you will 3 not -- and this paper actually calls for JOBS Act 2, 4 Part 2. You have to improve economic incentives to 5 support especially small cap stocks. And the way you -- 6 the way to do that, the best way to do that is to 7 increase tick sizes. 8 There's just a couple of guys recently -- and 9 we have these quotes in the study that we circulated. 10 There's one from John Bogle: "The financial 11 system has been wounded by a flood of so-called 12 innovations that merely promote hyper-rapid trading. 13 Individual investors are being shortchanged." 14 We have Professor Schwartz. And I don't know 15 if you know Bob, but Bob does this conference in New 16 York for the trading community, the exchange community. 17 And it is probably the best -- of course, he's been 18 doing it for years and years and years. And Bob said in 19 his opening remarks last year that, "Markets are still 20 adjusting to regulatory changes like the Order Handling 21 Rules and Reg ATS that were made over a decade ago." I 22 mean, again, back to the flesh-eating bacteria. 23 Then finally, Arthur Levitt, and this was on 24 "Bloomberg Surveillance" very recently, August 2nd. And 25 Arthur said, "The irony of this is that the change in 0084 1 the Order Handling Rules in 1997 that were instituted 2 under my watch at the SEC has resulted in the 3 proliferation of markets, technologies, and automation 4 that brought about the flash crash and yesterday's" -- 5 he's speaking about Knight Securities' algorithmic 6 issues -- "events. I think public confidence is 7 severely shaken by things of this kind." 8 And then my point is, is that there's just 9 lots of unintended consequences. And people are 10 beginning to realize that these two things, Order 11 Handling Rules and Reg ATS, had a pretty profound impact 12 on how markets change -- and while Arthur doesn't say 13 it, I will say it -- killing the IPO market. 14 Supportive observations from micro market 15 economists. And this is recently James Angel: "A large 16 relative tick provides an incentive for dealers to make 17 markets and for investors to provide liquidity by 18 placing limit orders." I know that Jim has spoken to 19 this Committee before. 20 David Allen, Josephine Sudiman in Indonesia. 21 Okay. This is an academic paper. "As tick size is 22 diminished, encouragement is given to front runners." 23 This is what we mentioned before, right, 24 stepping ahead. Traders are more reluctant to show 25 their orders. Things move into dark pools. 0085 1 By the way, you have to be careful when you set 2 tick size. You can't allow people to do all these 3 rebates and trade within the -- within the tick size 4 because then you defeat the purpose of the economic 5 incentive that you're trying to create. So if you do 6 payment for order flow, and if I earn a nickel, for the 7 sake of argument, and I can share that with somebody, 8 that this intermediates my tick size again. 9 David Bourghelle and Fany Declerck: "We find 10 that a relatively coarse pricing grid," okay, higher 11 tick size, "encourages traders to submit and expose 12 limit orders, while a tighter price grid induces 13 frequent undercutting strategies." 14 Michael Aitken and Carol Comerton-Forde in 15 Australia: "Stocks with relatively" -- "with small 16 relative tick sizes and low trading volume experience 17 reduced liquidity." 18 And Ed, he's going to talk about that in a 19 little bit. 20 But you cut tick sizes in micro cap, small cap 21 stocks, you harm liquidity. 22 I'm sorry. I think that -- go ahead. 23 MR. KIM: No, you're on a roll. Go. 24 We've talked about -- thank you, by the way, 25 for letting me -- letting me talk to you today. 0086 1 We've talked about the importance of tick 2 sizes, and it's not just -- although the focus is on 3 small and micro cap stocks, it's obviously critical for 4 large cap stocks as well. 5 And the studies have shown, both in academia 6 and practically by practitioners, that smaller tick 7 sizes do increase liquidity for large cap stocks, but 8 they absolutely decrease liquidity for small micro cap 9 stocks, which are -- which are naturally illiquid 10 anyway. And so they just -- they -- they aggravate the 11 current situation. 12 What smaller tick sizes do for large cap 13 stocks, however, that is violently negative is it 14 encourages and fosters this gaming behavior, this 15 undercutting or stepping-ahead behavior, where -- 16 whereby the high frequency trading firms and everybody 17 that isn't a non-fundamental trader, a non-fundamental 18 investor can be in and out of stocks -- for no reason 19 that is tied to investment, for no reason that is tied 20 to the long-term interest in the company, but is purely 21 about gaming for a penny in and out. 22 We have created a market that is absolutely a 23 market that a high frequency trader would have designed, 24 and is absolutely not the market that a long-term 25 investor has any interest in. 0087 1 And the -- if we can introduce larger tick 2 sizes, we can restore the conditions that created the 3 fertile ground that we had for IPOs for so long. So I'm 4 going to go through this, because I know we're running a 5 little bit -- a little bit late. 6 MR. GRAHAM: You're -- you're doing fine. 7 MR. KIM: Milton -- Milton Friedman said 8 there's -- to paraphrase, there's no such thing as a 9 free lunch. 10 And for us, it all -- it boils down I think to 11 economics. And with respect to Professor Ritter's 12 findings about economies of scale and economies of 13 scope, I do think that at the end of the day it's all 14 about the dollar. 15 If you follow investment banks, as an example, 16 which are -- which are critical for all this, we're 17 talking about restoring economics for investment banks. 18 Investment banks are only going to do the things that 19 make them money. It's not an indictment on the banks. 20 It is -- they're purely logical creatures. If Goldman 21 Sachs and Morgan Stanley could make money in small caps, 22 they'd be doing it. They'd be doing it all day long. 23 The fact that the small cap market has been 24 abandoned by the Goldmans and Morgans, the fact that 25 nobody has come in to replace Robertson, Hambrecht & 0088 1 Quist, Ellis, Rothschild, and Montgomery Securities, 2 nobody can make money. 3 If you look at what happened before Reg ATS, 4 or the conditions that existed before Reg ATS, you had, 5 as David alluded to, bankable spreads of a quarter a 6 share, 25 cents a share, which in the ensuing period 7 dropped to essentially a penny a share, a 96 percent 8 reduction in -- in the bankable spread, in the economics 9 to run the business. 10 If you take a business and you suck out 96 11 percent of the funding for that business, that business 12 cannot survive. 13 MR. WEILD: It's okay for naturally liquid S&P 14 500 stocks to let the orders interact, if you will. I 15 mean, there's enough incentive because of the sheer 16 scale volume. Some of these stocks trade in 20 million 17 shares a day. Right? 18 But when you get into things that are trading 19 episodically and trading in increments of 10,000 or 20 100,000 shares a day, it decimates them. There's just 21 not enough money in at -- when you go from a quarter 22 down to a penny. 23 MR. KIM: You have 167 different investment 24 banks book running deals in the early '90s. Post bubble 25 and post all of this, you were left with 39 banks. 0089 1 There's even fewer today who are -- who are running 2 deals. 3 MR. WALSH: You wouldn't say that across 4 myriad industries -- across -- 5 MR. KIM: Across myriad -- across every 6 industry. 7 MR. WALSH: That, to me, is irrelevant. So 8 what? 9 MR. WEILD: No, I think -- 10 MR. WALSH: Banks, are there 2,000 fewer 11 commercial banks in the States in that time period? 12 MR. BOCHNOWSKI: More than that. 13 MR. WALSH: Okay. So -- 14 MR. WEILD: What's happening, which is 15 catastrophic, is people are focusing on scale volume. 16 They're looking at economies of scale to move their 17 meter. You're a larger -- you're dealing with larger 18 and larger institutions that have no incentive to 19 support, you know, small and micro cap stocks. 20 MR. WALSH: I disagree. I think these high 21 frequency traders -- I don't want to belabor things -- 22 but they're essentially replacing -- 23 MR. WEILD: How? 24 MR. WALSH: -- they actually replaced them in 25 making liquidity. 0090 1 MR. WEILD: Oh, that's -- that's the biggest 2 joke on the face of the planet -- 3 (Talking simultaneously.) 4 MR. WALSH: (Inaudible.) 5 MR. WEILD: -- the fact that -- that's not 6 liquidity, guys. Average holding period is 11 seconds. 7 Okay? 8 (Talking simultaneously.) 9 MR. WALSH: (Inaudible.) 10 MR. WEILD: How is that liquidity? Does 11 anybody call -- call somebody and create an order on the 12 other side? It's not liquidity. 13 MR. WALSH: But -- 14 MR. WEILD: It's volume, it's volume. 70 15 percent of that stuff right now is volume. There's no 16 liquidity. It's the biggest lie that's been perpetrated 17 on the market that that's real liquidity. 18 MR. WALSH: And -- okay. If you want to go 19 back to the pre-'97 days, the way that the regulatory is 20 set up right now, these banks can't hold the train. 21 MR. WEILD: That the banks can't what? 22 MR. WALSH: Basel III coming down the road, 23 investments banks can't hold them to it. The Volcker rule, 24 I mean, they're basically telling you they don't want 25 people holding -- they don't want investment banks and 0091 1 commercial banks. 2 MR. WEILD: I mean, when you run a trading 3 desk -- first of all, you're not a storage department 4 when you're a market maker. What you're doing is you're 5 running a portfolio of long and short securities. And 6 so the actual capital committed to facilitate liquidity 7 is not huge, and it never was in the old days. 8 I mean, you know, I'll run -- I'll run an 9 equivalent -- if I want to be market neutral running a 10 trading desk, I'm going to be -- I may have, you know -- 11 I may have 1,000 positions out, 500 -- 550 of them are 12 long, and 450 of them are short. That's the way you do 13 it. Okay. So the actual capital, out-of-pocket capital 14 commitment is not huge. 15 And so what was huge was the incentive to get 16 on the phone to find the other side of the order when 17 somebody needed -- needed liquidity to be made. 18 I mean, there's -- the big difference between 19 S&P 500 stocks, you don't -- nobody was really making 20 markets per se in large cap stocks. 21 There's something called the Amivest liquidity 22 ratio, which looks at -- and by the way, liquidity is 23 how much stock can I move over a defined period -- a 24 defined period of time within a price tolerance. 25 And so you would find the Amivest liquidity 0092 1 ratio that -- that large cap S&P 500 stocks would be 2 over a half a billion dollars a pop. So there was no 3 specialist that could commit a half billion dollars' 4 worth of capital to move a stock 1 percent. They just 5 wouldn't. 6 So if you talk to Dick Grasso, which I have, 7 and Richard Bernard, who was the old General Counsel at 8 the New York Stock Exchange, they had an allocation 9 system. And they were actually, as a public policy 10 matter, enjoying excess profits on large cap stocks to 11 subsidize liquidity in micro caps. That's what went on. 12 Okay. But what happened was, those subsidies, 13 when you went -- when you convert to markets with Reg 14 ATS and then ultimately NMS, the ability to do all that 15 left the market and -- 16 So large cap, you know, again, you know, you 17 have natural liquidity, natural visibility, back to the 18 kind of the demand pull versus supply push stocks. Micro 19 cap's natural state is -- is supply push. People have 20 to get on the phone and create visibility. And that's 21 what's gone from the market. 22 MR. BORER: Because I live in this ecosystem, 23 I have for a long time, the number of market makers and 24 underwriters and those types of things around 20 years 25 ago, I'm familiar with some of the names you mentioned 0093 1 earlier. 2 There was -- there was not the gigantic gulf 3 that there is today between the few small firms that 4 will take on an underwriting firm for a company. And up 5 to the Jeffrey Siebold or even, you know, Raymond James 6 type people, from Loewen, Goldman, Citibank, Credit 7 Suisse, CPS, etc. So there's -- that group of people 8 has completely gone away through acquisition or just 9 dissipate, going out of business. There are no new -- 10 you know, take ten people out of Credit Suisse, start a 11 new firm, all of a sudden you have option for -- you 12 know, which becomes a firm. It's not happening. And 13 I'm not sure exactly why. 14 But I know I watch all the [SafePlace?]. This is 15 a very interesting thesis because margin came out of it, 16 not only the big end, but the small end. I think that's 17 what's taking place. 18 So to say that the 39 could do what the 167 19 used to do, they may, but they won't. Credit Suisse is 20 not going to do a $40 million deal. That seems to be 21 the decline in -- 22 MR. WALSH: There's also Morningstar. 23 MR. WEILD: They don't do underwriting. 24 MR. WALSH: Not underwriting, research, 25 research. 0094 1 MR. WEILD: No, but they don't call anybody on 2 the phone who's putting out research. So again it's the 3 demand pull versus -- 4 MR. WALSH: Still follow -- the world's 5 changed, in my opinion. 6 MR. WEILD: That's to the point -- 7 MR. WALSH: Also in 1997 there was ability to 8 enter, right? 9 MR. WEILD: You want to have a robust IPO 10 market with robust aftermarket support, you want to 11 drive job growth, economic reinvention in the U.S. 12 economy, you gotta put incentive back to support small 13 cap companies that require capital and actually drive 14 growth. 15 And if you don't, the world's changed 16 because -- remember, it's not the market. We create 17 markets. We create market incentives. You know, the 18 notion of the market decides, nonsense. 19 We created this market. We had the old 20 quote-driven market. We put a carrot out there. You 21 look at the credit crisis, we decided that we were going 22 to engage in liar loans and low interest rates, teaser 23 interest rates and no-money-down mortgages. And what 24 did we do? We created a bubble because we changed the 25 incentives. We changed the market structure. We 0095 1 changed the market structure here. 2 You gotta put it back to create incentives if 3 you -- if you care about this market. It's -- it's 4 binary. 5 MR. KIM: The one point I would make about -- 6 you had said that high frequency trading firms (“HFT firms”) have replaced the old 7 investment banks. And I think that's -- I think that's 8 a very unfair characterization. 9 High frequency trading firms live in the upper 10 end of the market, they live in stocks that trade 11 anyway. They create zero liquidity on the low end of 12 the market. And all they're creating really is 13 additional volume at the high end of the market. 14 So I don't think that HFT firms, despite how 15 they might want to portray themselves, have been 16 anything but -- but a negative for our markets. 17 DR. RITTER: You're saying for the micro cap 18 stocks, high frequency trading firms are -- 19 MR. KIM: They don't trade there. 20 MR. WEILD: They don't trade there. 21 DR. RITTER: And yet you're blaming them for 22 causing a problem there? 23 MR. KIM: No, no, I didn't say that. I don't 24 think I said that. No. I was trying to address Mr. 25 Walsh's comment about HFT firms replacing what the 0096 1 investment banks used to do. 2 DR. RITTER: Okay. But if HFT firms aren't 3 replacing investment banks with small cap stocks, why is 4 there a problem for investment banks? 5 MR. WEILD: Because the economic incentives 6 are gone, Jay. There's nobody -- nobody replacing what 7 the investment banks used to do for those small cap 8 stocks. 9 DR. RITTER: And what's your explanation for 10 why this spread has fallen there, then? 11 MR. WEILD: Well, first of all, a lot of those 12 small micro cap stocks -- I mean, I don't know, 13 you're -- I mean, I've been told that a lot of those 14 spreads are pretty fat, right? So -- 15 DR. RITTER: They are. 16 MR. WEILD: They are. Okay. And it's not a 17 spread issue; it's a bankable spread issue. Anybody can 18 step in front of you for a penny. So, you know, if I 19 need to get size done and I'm hanging out there, 20 somebody will step in front of you, Jay, if you're 21 sitting there trying to buy two -- getting 200,000 22 shares done, and they sniff that out, they will be in 23 front of you. 24 Now, the reason why the high frequency guy -- 25 by the way, if high frequency was adding liquidity, 0097 1 don't you think that they would be on the press and in 2 the market which is the most illiquid, which is the 3 micro caps? No, they're not there. They don't add 4 liquidity. 5 But there's -- you can't get something done in 6 the micro cap/nano cap space because people aren't 7 willing to make the risk. They're not making outbound 8 phone calls. 9 Micro cap liquidity is created by getting on 10 the phone and selling investors; stocks are sold, 11 they're not bought for the most part, with the exception 12 of the demand pull stocks, the big brand names, you 13 know. 14 And so what we've got is the -- what's the 15 median equity market value of a listed company in the 16 United States? It's $450 million. 17 DR. RITTER: Okay. But what I'm having 18 difficulty understanding is, if the bankable spread has 19 decreased for the small cap stocks, who is it who's 20 stepping in front? 21 MR. WEILD: If I want to go position 200,000 22 shares of stock right now in the market, I need to hold 23 that spread intact to be able to mark it up. If you say 24 the spread was a dime, it was 10 cents, and I buy it at 25 ten and I want to mark it up to ten-ten, okay, the 0098 1 minute somebody gets wind of the fact that I'm doing 2 some size in that market, they will step ahead of me for 3 a penny. 4 DR. RITTER: Okay. Who is -- who is this? 5 It's not the high frequency traders. 6 MR. WEILD: Anybody that has a trading machine 7 and an algorithm that sits there and sniffs something 8 out will be in front of me. A human being that sees me 9 do that will step in front of me for a penny. 10 MR. KIM: The high frequency firms are going 11 to go wherever -- wherever there is significant and 12 sufficient volume. That's where they'll live. They 13 live now -- they live now, and they've lived for years 14 now, at the high end of the market. They're not 15 creating any new liquidity at the low end of the market. 16 If we try, to David's point, their algorithms would 17 sniff out any irregularity, any -- any difference in the 18 normal day-to-day volume. And any attempt to introduce, 19 you know, a position of 30 days' worth of trading 20 volume, for example, into the lower end of the market -- 21 MR. WEILD: I can't -- 22 MR. KIM: -- it wouldn't work. 23 MR. WEILD: I can't get compensated for taking 24 that risk as a trader, Jay. Okay? I mean, if I'm 25 sitting there and I'm hanging out and I make a capital 0099 1 commitment on 200,000 shares of stock at ten bucks a 2 share, $2 million, the risk then, probability of it that 3 somebody sees me doing that, buying that stock, and 4 pushes it down to a lower price, it -- it -- my upside 5 potential is capped at a penny, if somebody -- if 6 somebody steps in front of me for a penny, and my 7 downside is that I'm long 2 million shares of stock that 8 somebody pushes down a nickel or a quarter, the math 9 doesn't work any longer. It's just that the model is 10 dead. 11 And that's what you've seen in terms of 12 wholesale shifts in markets. I mean, I'm looking at 13 John. You know, John Borer, but your firm, you know, 14 people used to make a lot of money getting on the phone, 15 creating visibility. 16 Again, it's not -- it's less a research 17 problem. It's, what do you do with the salesmen, the 18 sales traders all making phone calls? They're the 19 amplification system, if you will, for research. 20 Research gives you a pretext for a 21 conversation, but he's only one guy. So how many phone 22 calls can he make? 23 But if you need to move size, a block of 24 200,000 shares, and you've got a sales force of 35 guys 25 and, you know, 20 sales traders, all of a sudden people 0100 1 are out there finding the other side of the order. But 2 they have to be incented to do that. 3 And if you position it -- and the upside is 4 now down to a penny because somebody can step in front 5 of you for a penny, you will -- you will very quickly 6 lose a ton of dough committing capital to those stocks. 7 You know, Dan, I don't know at Wasatch, but, 8 you know, people used to commit lots of capital in the 9 micro cap names. Nobody commits capital down there any 10 longer. You know that. 11 I mean, I'm not telling anybody -- this 12 shouldn't be revelatory, at least for people that are in 13 the business. People don't commit capital. Get on a 14 trading desk. Okay. And for those of you that were on 15 the trading desk 15, 20 years ago, it was a pretty noisy 16 environment. People were talking to each other, picking 17 up the phone. Now you can hear a computer. You know, 18 all you -- all you -- all you hear is the whir of 19 computers. It's deathly silent. But there's nobody, 20 nobody on the phone. 21 And, in fact, if you go to a morning call, 22 institutionally, one of the things that happens is that, 23 you know, they -- a lot of times they -- the research 24 salesmen will get voicemail. And they've automated 25 things with computer-aided telephone, and they just take 0101 1 a -- one voicemail message and they -- if they get the 2 voicemail, they just drop it into the voicemail box. 3 They hit the button, hit the button, hit the button, hit 4 the button. 5 So that -- those things have changed the whole 6 ability to market. And you've been forced to do that 7 because the economics of the business are just 8 unprofitable. So you're only paying for a trade, for a 9 trade execution. That's what's in the market. All the 10 value components that are required to support a small 11 cap infrastructure in this country have been starved. 12 MR. CHACE: Can I ask a bit of a different 13 question? I mean, we were talking about markets, and 14 markets have provided innovation and created value in 15 finding ways to capture that value. And Professor 16 Ritter has argued that there's value in research 17 coverage in terms of higher stock prices, and hopefully 18 in terms of generating ideas for investors to make 19 money. You've argued -- or I think would argue that 20 there's value in providing liquidity to institutional 21 investors to buy and sell securities in bulk. 22 Are there alternative models? I mean, beyond 23 what I think I kind of read this, and I'm not an expert 24 by any means, but it kind of feels like a tax on 25 investors to fund something. 0102 1 But are there different models rather than 2 tick sizes that would sort of facilitate what you're 3 describing? 4 MR. WEILD: Well, it's an economic incentive 5 issue, Dan. And I, you know, mentioned there's three 6 ways you can be: You can either be back at a 7 quote-driven market, you can up commissions, or you can 8 up tick sizes. 9 But the one that I think works for 10 institutional investors, from my conversations with, you 11 know, Karey, you know, Barker, we talked about the 12 accounting issue -- that's one of the senior -- you 13 know, one of -- one of Dan's colleagues -- is -- is it 14 has to be in the cost basis, the stock and mutual funds 15 to work, and tick sizes does that. 16 With commissions it will actually go into the 17 expense ratios. And then Morningstar ratings for small 18 cap growth managers would actually look less attractive 19 relative to large cap funds. And that wouldn't -- that 20 wouldn't get us where we need to go. 21 So it's economic incentive. 22 There may be a different way that I haven't 23 thought of. I'm not a proponent -- for instance, 24 there's been some discussion in Congress about just flat 25 out, you know, because of the high frequency stuff, just 0103 1 taxing stock transactions. But the problem is that then 2 the money doesn't go into the -- you know, into the 3 market, into the ecosystem. And if you don't have a -- 4 have an economic linkage with the tax, with the value 5 creation of that, which is creating the liquidity, then 6 why are people going to get into the business of 7 creating liquidity. 8 And one of the reasons why that model you 9 talked about, the research -- the paid research model 10 that NASDAQ and Reuters tried to do, one of the reasons 11 why it failed was also because -- not because simply it 12 was $120,000, is that it was $120,000 for a research 13 report that wasn't going to then actively get marketed 14 because there was no economic incentive to market it in 15 the aftermarket and drive volume and visibility. 16 So you got research coverage, and it works for 17 some institutions and some investors that are smart 18 enough to go track down the research, but it doesn't 19 actually do the other piece of it, which is create 20 active visibility and active liquidity through 21 marketing. 22 Does that make sense? 23 DR. RITTER: Okay. I thought institutions 24 were willing to pay soft dollars as a way of incentive, 25 you know, giving knowledge to the analyst. 0104 1 MR. WEILD: Yeah, but a soft dollar -- I'll 2 pay -- I'll pay you on a micro cap trade with a trade in 3 IBM all day long for the research. It doesn't actually 4 help the liquidity creation of the micro cap name. It 5 may do that. 6 You know, I mean, guys are -- guys are -- you 7 know, I don't trust you to do an execution on this micro 8 cap name or whatever, so I'll go execute it through 9 somebody who's my preferred trader, and I'll pay you 10 with things that are totally irrelevant, totally 11 different industry, you'll get those trades over your 12 desk in soft dollars all the time. Right. 13 Dan? 14 MR. CHACE: Yeah. There's execution and less 15 execution paid for that. But it's true, as David said, 16 it's not always addressed. You add value on this side; 17 therefore, you trade. 18 MR. WEILD: And institutions will sit there, 19 and, you know, they'll go through what they call the 20 broker vote and they'll decide, this is how much -- this 21 is what we think our commission pie is going to look 22 like, and this is how much we have to pay this firm, 23 this is how much we have to pay this firm during the 24 course of the year. 25 So the actual linkage is -- is not necessarily 0105 1 there. It's about the holistic relationship. And the 2 trader has discretion on the desk to -- you know, he's 3 just got to make sure that he gets a certain amount of 4 commissions to that firm during the course of the year. 5 But how he does it is entirely up to him to 6 get the best price execution for each of the funds that 7 are under management. 8 Okay. Sorry. 9 MR. GRAHAM: David, this is all very 10 interesting. It's great. 11 How much more time do you need? 12 MR. KIM: I need -- I need two more minutes, 13 and then -- and then I'm done. 14 MR. WEILD: Then I want to get into 15 recommendations. 16 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. So five, ten minutes? 17 MR. WEILD: Yeah, ten, give us ten. 18 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. Give you ten. 19 MR. KIM: We've covered this, but this is -- 20 what the current level covers is only the cost of 21 execution. We have lost the ability to cover the costs 22 of the elements that were needed to create liquidity. 23 So, you know, it's capital commitment, sales research, 24 creating visibility. This is essentially an 25 execution-only market now. 0106 1 In recent months, from a very broad 2 cross-section of market practitioners, everyone from 3 exchange specialists to academics to small investment 4 banks, we've seen growing recognition of our assertion 5 that increase in tick sizes is a viable and necessary 6 way to go. Everyone from Duncan Niederauer with the New 7 York Stock Exchange who has said on the record that 8 they've been looking at this internally, and that it 9 would be fairly easy to implement; Kevin Cronin, head of 10 trading at Invesco; William O'Brien of Direct Edge; Jim 11 Toes, the president of the Securities Traders 12 Association. 13 We have -- at the Congressional Subcommittee 14 hearing that David was at two months ago, we heard from 15 a very broad cross-section of folks that all were in 16 support, universally in support of at least a pilot 17 study to explore what happens with tick sizes. 18 MR. WEILD: The Investment Company Institute 19 that represents the mutual fund industry came out for it 20 in Congress. 21 MR. KIM: So this is -- this will be our -- or 22 my last line, and then I'll let David go. 23 If you look at all of the potential causes, 24 and, again, bearing in mind that timeline that you saw 25 before from when Reg ATS was first instituted, 0107 1 Sarbanes-Oxley -- we're not saying that Sarbanes-Oxley 2 has no effect. Clearly it has effect, clearly it has a 3 cost impact. 4 But based on two things: Based on the timing 5 of Sarbanes, which was in 2002, and based on the actual 6 amount of dollars involved, we think that the impact of 7 Sarbanes-Oxley on the IPO market itself has actually 8 been very small. And we also -- I absolutely respect 9 Professor Ritter's studies and his thesis about 10 economies of scope, but, again, I think the notion that 11 small firms can create more profits by selling 12 themselves to larger firms, a lot of that is technology 13 driven, a lot of that I think is, as it relates to the 14 IPO market itself, again, I think the -- I think the 15 impact is very small. 16 The largest impact that we have seen boils 17 down to the economics available for the intermediaries 18 in the business, which are the investment banks and 19 brokers, to create the support infrastructure that 20 worked for decades in this market. For decades. 21 And the dire situation that we find ourselves 22 in today I think is the inevitable consequence of the 23 loss of the economic infrastructure. We are today 24 exactly where we were destined to be once we sucked the 25 economics out of the system. 0108 1 MR. WEILD: We had -- I'm just going to plow 2 through these very quickly. This is about equity 3 distribution infrastructure and how it's eroded. And, 4 you know, there's -- every single bulge bracket, major 5 bracket firm handling middle market institutional sales 6 desks, they've all been shuttered. 7 The top 60 accounts represent about 90 percent 8 of the top commission opportunity institutionally for 9 firms. A lot of it is coming from the lending business, 10 and prime brokerage is no longer even stocked. So if 11 you want to get out -- if you want to see who's 12 distributing to the smaller institutions, basically 13 nobody. I mean, you can't -- there's about 3,000 14 institutions in the United States right now that have 15 over a hundred million dollars. 16 And so Dan Chace is not getting an allocation 17 on a new issue, even though he's a growth manager with 18 $12 billion under -- under management for most of the 19 time because he's not big enough to be covered 20 effectively by Morgan Stanley. And actually, at $12 21 billion, he's -- there are a lot of institutions that 22 are not getting allocations at $50 billion in assets 23 under management. I mean, that's how big the cutoff is. 24 And people are chasing the dollar. 25 We're going to go flip through -- 0109 1 MR. KIM: The most active hedge funds pay 2 investment banks in excess of a hundred million dollars 3 a year in their total relationship. Stevie Cohen pays 4 Goldman Sachs well over a hundred million dollars a 5 year. 6 So your CEO, with a hundred million dollar IPO 7 that's going to generate at best three million bucks, 8 you're not the customer anymore, you're food, and that's 9 the problem. 10 MR. WEILD: You know, you talked about this is 11 trailing 30 IPOs, you know, and this is -- you know, one 12 of the things that I do agree with Jay is that if these 13 things are not supported and properly distributed, and 14 they're not being priced on fundamentals because they're 15 going to too many -- too many people that are not really 16 focused on the fundamentals, they're renters, not owners 17 to the stocks, we're seeing IPO success rates decline. 18 And when people lose money, then the window shuts; you 19 can't keep it open. It's pretty simple. 20 MR. KIM: And this is for large -- it's for 21 larger deals as well. It's not just on small deals. 22 IPO success rates on all deals of any size have 23 declined. 24 MR. WEILD: So I -- and by the way, the SEC 25 has been inundated with information mostly on the S&P 0110 1 500. And you can see how different these markets are. 2 This is where the S&P 500 is, and this is where the 3 Russell 2000 -- even the Russell 2000 has -- is -- is -- 4 which people use as the small cap index, is bigger on 5 average than where this dysfunction is occurring. 6 So, you know, you can't -- and by the way, a 7 lot of the data on the Russell 2000 says that spreads 8 haven't come in. So you can imagine, a lot of them in 9 the micro cap/nano cap may have even -- even -- even 10 widened. I don't know, I haven't seen any analysis on 11 that. 12 But that certainly is the trend line. You can 13 see this is the market value of these stocks. The 14 number of stocks are all clustered down at the bottom, 15 and -- and -- and this is the market value up here. 16 And as you can see, these stocks down where 17 capital formation lives are totally different because 18 they represent only 6.6 percent of market value spread 19 across -- spread across a large 81 -- -1.1 percent of 20 all publicly listed companies. 21 So just right into recommendations. And what 22 we've been able to, you know, surmise, we think that you 23 need to do mass customization of tick sizes because one 24 size doesn't fit all. And there's a lot of people that 25 would argue if you could have even small tick sizes in 0111 1 S&P 500 stocks. And the question is: Do you want to 2 proliferate gaming and stepping ahead and those kinds of 3 behaviors? 4 But at the end of the day, the downside is 5 probably not great for the market. But where it is, is 6 that you need higher tick sizes to support small caps. 7 And every stock is different. The mini 8 micros, the nano caps are going to require higher tick 9 sizes than a -- than a micro and than a small cap stock, 10 so on and so forth. 11 Then the question is: How do you create a 12 system where the market can determine tick sizes? 13 Well, there's two methodologies here that 14 could work that we've come up with, one of which was 15 from conversation we had with stock exchanges, and one 16 which was ours, which Professor Angel has endorsed, 17 which is allow issuers to choose their tick size after 18 consultation, if you will, with institutional investors 19 and with Wall Street firms. Because what you're trying 20 to do is figure out, how do I get people to pay 21 attention? Okay. And so if you have a lever, maybe 22 that's within some tolerance, zero to 5 percent of the 23 share price. 24 The other one is to try and think about doing 25 it algorithmically. And you can use the algorithmic 0112 1 methodology as a default, which basically says, here's 2 the spread for the last year, and we're going to make 3 spread equivalent to tick size, which creates a bankable 4 spread, converts a quoted spread to a bankable spread. 5 So if it's -- the market has also already sort 6 of determined that the average trading spread is a dime, 7 then make that the tick size. It's pretty simple. 8 Because nobody can monetize it anyway. So at least you 9 create value by incentivising investors to -- market makers 10 and others to kind of go after that spread. 11 So those are the two concepts. This is the -- 12 you know, how the range would work on share prices so, 13 you know, the SEC could oversee this. 14 And then here's -- you know, here's just the 15 basic math of the algorithm. It's pretty darn simple; 16 it would be pretty simple to implement across the 17 market. 18 And -- and then finally, with -- you know, 19 these are some -- this was something that was socialized 20 at NIRI, National Investor Relations Institute, which is 21 just an issuer bill of rights which -- that we think 22 that issuers and issuer advocates need to have an equal 23 voice in stock market structure. And sometimes we think 24 that the traders inundate the trading interest, inundate 25 the Division of Trading and Markets. I've said this to 0113 1 Chairman Schapiro, by the way, probably about a year ago. 2 And so I would like to see Gerry Laporte's 3 group, which represents small companies, represented in, 4 you know, an equivalent kind of structure in the 5 Division of Trading and Markets, because I think you 6 guys are confined to Corporation Finance, if I'm 7 not mistaken. 8 At any rate, I may be wrong about that, but it 9 just appears outwardly that when you take Reg ATS and 10 Reg NMS and you proliferate lots of stock exchanges that 11 don't represent any issuer interest -- there's only two, 12 NASDAQ and then New York, and there's about 13 exchanges 13 in total and all sorts of Reg ATS -- that you're going 14 to have lots of trading-only interests that are lobbying 15 the SEC and Congress for things that are really 16 beneficial to electronic execution and trading and not 17 necessarily in the best interest of issuers. It's 18 just -- you know, it's outsize representation. 19 We'd like to create greater transparency, 20 timeliness, and completeness in terms of share -- share 21 ownership. And there's no reason why people shouldn't 22 be able to understand who's shorting their stock. 23 I get very, very fit to be tied when I see 24 issuers wasting tons of time being dragged around to see 25 hedge funds and other people that are doing damage to 0114 1 their stock when they should be back in the office 2 running their business. 3 And because the lack of transparency on this 4 information -- by the way, you have insider trading 5 issues you'd have to control around, but they really 6 should have real-time information. Every CEO deserves 7 that, in my judgment. 8 Choice in market structure. Again, no more 9 one size fits all. You can do it with sort of the -- 10 lots of things that you can do. But we are now a 11 country with one tick size and one market structure all 12 homogenized because of Regulation National Market 13 System. And that is a lot of systemic risk. We bet 14 everything on black here. We have no choice. 15 And then finally market structures that 16 encourage fundamental investing over training. This is 17 a very trading-centric market. 18 And we need to get people back to basics. We 19 need -- we need firms like Wasatch -- I don't want to 20 pick on you, Dan, but these are the firms that are going 21 to lead us going forward and going to allocate capital 22 efficiently in the marketplaces. And we need -- we 23 need -- we need market structures that favor fundamental 24 investors like the Wasatches, the AllianceBernsteins of 25 the world, and not trading centric hedge funds that are 0115 1 long shorts, where -- where the idea of a long-term hold 2 is buy it on the open and sell it on the close. 3 MS. HANLEY: Great. Thank you. I have just 4 one question as we go through this. 5 So I'm hearing from you that there are a 6 certain amount of profitability from the investment 7 banking side or the trading side that should be earned 8 in the market, and that these changes, regulation 9 changes that we have done has taken away rent from 10 investment bankers and given them essentially to 11 investors. They're trading at too low a price and then 12 investment bankers can no longer make any money. 13 So you want to swing the pendulum, I 14 understand, back to sort of more of the middle ground 15 where those rents can be split perhaps more evenly. 16 Do you have some idea of what is the 17 appropriate split, so to speak? What is the -- if -- 18 when we -- if we were to change tick sizes, how do we 19 quantify where that tick size should be that we now have 20 a better understanding of, you know, how much should go 21 to the market maker vis-a-vis how much should be going 22 to the investor? Do you have a sense of how we would 23 measure that? 24 MR. WEILD: I think that, you know, the market 25 to some degree, I think, Kathleen, is already -- already 0116 1 telling you a little bit where the spreads are. I think 2 that the spread is a pretty good indicia. If it's 3 sitting there on average over time at 20 cents, I mean, 4 that's probably -- you know, it's not doing -- it's not 5 creating any value for anybody. Make the spread, you 6 know, 20 cents. 7 You could look at how the quote-driven market 8 actually occurred before the IPO dysfunction, you know, 9 happened in 1998. 10 And for a long time, we had two ticks per 11 quarter point. Right? It was an 1/8 -- it was a 1/8 12 tick. And it allowed institutions, if you will, to -- 13 for the most part, to trade within this spread. 14 And so you could, you know -- you could 15 play -- I mean, if I was going to do it, I would 16 probably sit there and say, take the spread, do one 17 sample set at a -- at a -- at -- where the tick is equal 18 to the natural spread. And I would take another sample 19 set and maybe experiment with, you know, two ticks or 20 three ticks and see what happened. 21 The problem is you're going to get -- if you 22 do a pilot study around that, you're going to get 23 short-term interest. But the real hard-core, long-term 24 investments and people resources are not going to 25 accelerate until people know that the pilot is -- 0117 1 MS. HANLEY: Yeah, that -- well, that -- that 2 is definitely a challenge with the pilot. 3 And more importantly, I think it's important 4 that we get the number right so that the incentives 5 occur, right? 6 MR. WEILD: Right. 7 MS. HANLEY: If we set the tick sizes too 8 small, again, we'll be in the same realm. 9 MR. WEILD: But -- 10 MS. HANLEY: If we set it too large, we'll 11 drive away investors. And so we don't need to answer it 12 here -- 13 MR. WEILD: But -- but -- 14 MS. HANLEY: -- but as an advisory committee 15 and as the -- 16 MR. WEILD: Well -- 17 MS. HANLEY: -- roundtable will occur, I think 18 it's important that we think-- 19 MR. WEILD: But we also said, you know, why 20 not let -- why not let issuers choose? Because I think 21 that at some point they're going to get beat -- they 22 want to get interest, they're going to get beaten up by, 23 you know, Wasatch. 24 I mean, they're not going to be -- they're not 25 going to be coy. They're going to say the tick size is 0118 1 too high. The bankers are going to say the tick size is 2 too low. 3 At some point, people have to come up -- by 4 the way, it would put -- it would cause issuers to 5 finally take an interest in market structure and how it 6 impacts, you know, their -- their stock prices. 7 And so there are some problems; you know, 8 everybody is uncomfortable with the idea. But the fact 9 of the matter is that one tick size doesn't fit all. 10 And a chemical stock with a hundred million 11 dollar flow, for the sake of argument, is going to 12 trade -- has a very different ecosystem than a “SaaS” 13 stock, a software as a services company. There's a lot 14 more research analysts, if you will, naturally around 15 SaaS as an industry than there are -- and market 16 participants, than they are necessarily around certain 17 small cap chemical stocks. And so -- so the answer is 18 going to be different for them. 19 So whether that -- you take the natural spread 20 and set it equivalent to the tick size, you let 21 issuers -- you get -- you get to -- you get to a model 22 which is mass customization of tick size, which I think 23 is the right answer. 24 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. Well, thank you. Thank 25 you again, David. 0119 1 Lona, do you want to go into JOBS Act? 2 MR. NALLENGARA: Sure. I think I can update 3 on what's happened since our last meeting with respect 4 to the JOBS Act. 5 One of the larger events was our proposing 6 release of Title II. Title II is the general 7 solicitation. We talked about it at a couple of 8 meetings. 9 There was a provision in the JOBS Act that 10 would remove the restriction on general advertising in Rule 11 506 offerings. These are private placements. Under 12 Rule 506, currently you cannot advertise, you can't have 13 newspaper ads, you can't have an open access website. 14 Title II would now permit you to do that if you only 15 sold securities to accredited investors. 16 And in the JOBS Act, they added an additional 17 provision to that that requires an issuer to take steps 18 to verify that who they're actually selling to are 19 accredited investors. 20 It's somewhat straightforward to remove the 21 restriction on general solicitation. It's a little 22 more challenging outlining what those procedures are for 23 an issuer to take to verify who your accredited investor 24 is. 25 If you're an institution, if you're a 0120 1 broker-dealer, showing or -- or providing an issuer with 2 some verification that you are -- rather, an accredited 3 investor, it's likely to be straightforward. 4 But if you're an individual, providing support 5 that you are an accredited investor could be more 6 challenging. There's a net income test, there's a net 7 worth test. 8 So when this provision was included in the 9 JOBS Act and enacted, people were asking questions on 10 how would you go about and -- and -- how would an issuer 11 verify that someone is an accredited investor or not? 12 Would they need a W-2? Would they need to get -- would 13 they need to see tax returns? Would they need to have 14 bank statements? How would an issuer know that they 15 were selling to an accredited investor? So that's what 16 we were left with in connection with the rulemaking. 17 And the proposal that came out last week 18 creates a -- creates a framework where an issuer has to 19 look at the facts and circumstances of the transaction. 20 How are they finding their -- how are they finding the 21 purchaser of their securities? Are they -- are these 22 long-time holders of their securities? Are 23 broker-dealers providing them with the connection with 24 those -- with those purchasers, or are these individuals 25 that they're finding because they are clicking a page on 0121 1 their website that says buy securities. So that's one 2 part of the package in this analysis. 3 You could also look at, what are the terms of 4 the offering? Is there a minimum investment amount? Is 5 the amount that a purchaser is required to buy high 6 enough that you are -- that that's a fact you can look 7 at to determine that that person is a person who's an 8 accredited investor? If there's a $5 million minimum 9 investment amount,it's not hard to make an assessment 10 that that person may have a net worth in excess of -- in 11 excess of a million dollars. 12 So we – in the proposing release, the Commission 13 made clear that they weren't identifying specific 14 procedures that you had to do in a particular 15 circumstance. But rather, look at your -- asking 16 issuers to look at the facts and circumstances of the 17 transaction and make an assessment of what are -- what 18 would be appropriate, given what you know about the 19 purchaser, how you found the purchaser, and the nature 20 of the transaction. Take those steps and make an 21 assessment of what needs to be done. 22 So that's, in a nutshell, the proposal. 23 One additional part of the proposal is that 24 there is a Form D requirement for when you complete a 25 506 offering. You are supposed to file a Form D. 0122 1 What we've proposed to include is a box that 2 you check on the form that would indicate that you 3 are -- you, as part of the offering, you generally 4 solicited or not. This is a way for us to be able to 5 track, identify which offerings, which market 6 participants have been participating in offerings where 7 there's general solicitation. 8 So we can go back and look, after the rules are adopted, 9 to see what procedures are being used, is the framework 10 that we've set up one that works, and be able to look at 11 the market more generally. 12 So that's the proposal. There's a 30-day 13 comment period. We expect, as there was in the comments 14 before we proposed the rule, we expect there would be a 15 wide range of views. Many people have indicated that 16 they're -- that they like the proposal. And as you can 17 imagine, there are alot of people who said they don't agree 18 with the proposal. So we're hoping to hear from 19 everyone on that. 20 I'm not sure if anyone has any questions on 21 the proposal. 22 MR. WALSH: What are some of the reasons 23 against it? 24 MR. NALLENGARA: Well, some of the reasons are 25 that there should be more definitive requirements. Some 0123 1 are saying there should be more definitive requirements. 2 You should be -- you should be -- there should be more 3 onus on an issuer who's doing a general solicitation 4 deal to have more third-party information, documented 5 information. So there are -- I think there are probably 6 letters on our site that indicate that the issuer 7 should be getting some third-party information to 8 support whether an issuer -- whether a purchaser is 9 actually an accredited investor. 10 MR. WALSH: W-2s. 11 MR. NALLENGARA: W-2s. And there are letters 12 on the other side saying that would grind -- that would 13 grind the 506 offering to a halt, that people just wouldn't -- I 14 mean, if I'm -- if I'm -- I wouldn't want -- you know, 15 it's one thing to provide information to a 16 broker-dealer. I'd be more comfortable, some of the 17 comments are saying, I'm comfortable giving that 18 information to a broker-dealer. But if this provision 19 is designed to allow issuers to access the market 20 without a broker-dealer if they don't want to, if they 21 want to access it on their own, am I -- is a person 22 going to be willing to provide that information just to 23 the issuer that they've never met before? They have no 24 idea, there's certain kind of privacy rights concerns. 25 So there's other comments indicated that if 0124 1 you're going to allow for general solicitation, there's 2 lots more stuff you should be looking at. 3 The definition of accredited investor, many 4 people have said for a long time that definition is an 5 old definition. You shouldn't just be looking at net 6 worth, you shouldn't just be looking at income. You 7 should be looking at investment. How much money do you 8 have invested in private securities? Is that a better 9 test? 10 And there's Dodd-Frank, which tasked the 11 GAO to do studies that will be coming in the next year 12 that would look at the accredited investor definition 13 broadly. 14 So what the -- what the Chairman's statement 15 at the time of the proposal was, there's lots of 16 stuff within the 506 market, specifically about Reg D 17 generally, that needs to be looked at. The definition. And 18 the form itself, the one where we propose having a box 19 checked. 20 There's lots more information we could ask 21 for. We could ask for -- you know, we could -- we -- a 22 lot of information could be drawn from that that would 23 help us understand what the market is like. All of that 24 is, you know, subject to review. 25 But the terms was Title II requirement, what 0125 1 Congress asked us to do was a narrow one, so we focused 2 just on that narrow part. So other -- I'm sorry. 3 MS. MOTT: I have a question. 4 MR. NALLENGARA: Yes. 5 MS. MOTT: I can see where in a case where a 6 company that's raising -- a startup company that's 7 raising money, the ruling can apply to both. 8 You know, if they're going to give it to a 9 crowd funding issuer, you know, obviously because you 10 can't tax -- to answer your question, it can bring and 11 attract people who might not be accredited. So you 12 really have to find a way they are accredited. 13 But let's say they're going to generally 14 advertise through this issuer who's online or whatever 15 else, but then doesn't raise enough money, now has to 16 come to, you know, the angel group, let's say, who, by 17 the way, aren't going to give the entrepreneur who's 18 coming to them their information, you know, their tax 19 returns, their, you know, net worth statements, things 20 like that. 21 So in this case, we have the ruling applying 22 over here, but maybe all of a sudden now they're not 23 going -- not going to -- it's not general advertising or 24 it is because it's accredited investors who have 25 invested in, you know, these types of companies before. 0126 1 I mean, I guess I'm a little confused by it. 2 MR. NALLENGARA: I think -- what you're asking 3 is -- 4 MS. MOTT: Am I asking? I don't have -- 5 MR. NALLENGARA: If you start an offering as a 6 general offering, is that -- 7 MS. MOTT: That's it. 8 MR. NALLENGARA: Well, there's a lot of 9 questions on it. We have a number of rules related 10 to -- related to integrating an offering, whether if you 11 generally solicit in an offering and then continue, can 12 you -- for example, you know, real quick, the rule 13 proposal keeps intact the current Rule 507. 14 If you want to do your regular way 506 15 offering where you're not -- you're using a broker, 16 you're using your existing investors, you don't 17 necessarily have to -- you don't have to go through -- 18 you don't have to look at this new proposal for the 19 final rule. You can continue to use your established 20 procedures. 21 If you want to generally solicit, that means 22 if you want to have newspaper ads, if you want have a 23 website, then you need to look at the verification 24 standard. 25 What the practices are now currently may 0127 1 already satisfy that verification. A lot of 2 companies that are doing current practice 506 offerings 3 are using practices that are -- that would be consistent 4 with this verification model. 5 So if a company starts an offering by way 6 of -- by way of a general solicitation, and they want to 7 move back to a sort of regular 506 offering, what 8 they're going to have to look at is they're going to 9 have to look -- it's not as easy as saying, yes, they 10 can do it. They're going to have to look at what general 11 solicitation activities they're going to do and whether 12 that -- whether general solicitation is in fact how your 13 folks for the angel network have been attracted. 14 But I would gather that there's probably 15 methods by which your network could establish 16 accreditation levels for members that would satisfy 17 the requirement. 18 The rule proposal suggests there will likely 19 be third parties that will develop -- that will accredit 20 investors. So SecondMarket has indicated that they -- 21 this is an area that they'd like to work in as being a 22 repository of accredited investors. So you could get -- you 23 know, you could get the SecondMarket stance that would 24 say this person is an accredited investor. We've looked 25 at their -- you know, we've looked at their information. 0128 1 They were -- and -- and an investor may be more 2 comfortable providing information to a known entity, whether it's an 3 angel investor or whether it's SecondMarket or some 4 other third party. It would be a way which -- you don't 5 necessarily have to provide that information to the 6 issuer. 7 MS. SMITH: So the company sells shares based 8 on the representation certified by the third-party but it turns out that the person is a 9 non-accredited investor where -- is there a 10 violation of that rule? Is there going to be a filing 11 rule? 12 MR. NALLENGARA: That's a great question, 13 Karen. The current rule, as well as the proposal, has a 14 reasonable belief standard on it. So if you've taken steps to verify, and 15 the person -- and the person -- let's say they went 16 through a third party, and the third party is 17 documenting the procedures they go through in 18 establishing whether someone is an accredited investor, 19 and they certify to the issuer that we've checked -- 20 we've checked Karen Smith, and we've gone through what 21 our normal procedures are, and Karen Smith is an 22 accredited investor. And I rely on that information, and we find 23 out that you doctored, you gave a fake tax return, I 24 still have a good -- I still have a good 506. It's sort 25 of reasonable for me to rely on this third-party 0129 1 established procedure. I wouldn't lose my 506. 2 Actually, there are a number of cases where 3 individuals who have -- who have faked their accredited 4 investor status, have purchased securities, then wanted 5 to rescind the transaction because they weren't an 6 accredited investor. And they have been unsuccessful. 7 So I'm not sure that was a plan of yours. 8 MS. SMITH: No, not a plan. 9 MR. NALLENGARA: I think we're at 12:00. We 10 have -- for the members we have lunch. And Marc -- I 11 think I saw Marc. Marc Fagel, who's the head of our San 12 Francisco office, was going to talk to everyone about 13 some areas of interest to small companies unrelated to both 14 topics today, but we thought it would be interesting for 15 all of you to hear that. 16 Steve, you want to take ten minutes while we 17 get lunch together, and then we'll reconvene? I think 18 Marc will speak for about 15 minutes, and then we'll -- 19 and then I guess sort of have free time back until 1:00. 20 MR. GRAHAM: Perfect. 21 MR. NALLENGARA: Okay. 22 MR. GRAHAM: Let's do it. 23 MR. NALLENGARA: Sorry. So if you wanted -- 24 the security is a little different than our meetings in 25 headquarters. So you're obviously allowed to leave and 0130 1 we'll all -- and we'll let you back in. But it's a 2 little more challenging to get back into the building 3 than it is at Headquarters. So I guess for the members, 4 we're going to reconvene in about ten minutes, lunch, 5 and then Marc will speak. And then if you want to 6 leave, you just have to -- you have to come back closer 7 to 1:00. Come back to the 28th floor, and we'll bring 8 you all back down again. 9 For those in the public who want to leave and 10 come back at 1:00, if you can just come back at ten 11 minutes to 1:00, go back to the 28th floor, then we'll 12 come and get you and bring you back down. 13 MS. ZEPRALKA: If any members of the public are leaving and not coming back for the afternoon session, please hand me your lanyards on the way out. 14 MR. GRAHAM: Great. 15 MR. NALLENGARA: Back in ten minutes. 16 (Whereupon, at 12:01 p.m., a luncheon recess 17 was taken.) 18 A F T E R N O O N S E S S I O N 19 (12:23 p.m.) 20 MR. GRAHAM: Committee members, time for 21 noontime program. And as I think you know, Marc 22 Fagel -- I guess you're based in San Francisco -- has 23 agreed to spend some time with us talking about some of 24 the -- some of the important issues, I understand, the 25 effect on smaller companies. 0131 1 I think we're going to hear a little bit 2 about -- more about the traffic is going to get worse 3 and essentially how to keep out of trouble. And kind of 4 stay in the terms of time. 5 MR. FAGEL: Well, thank you. Yes, so my name 6 is Marc Fagel. I'm the Regional Director of this 7 office, and I welcome all of you to our new facility. 8 Hopefully things are working -- working well. 9 We've got about just over 100 folks out here, 10 about half of whom do enforcement, the other half are 11 examiners and broker-dealers and advisors in funds and 12 the like. 13 But I'm here to talk about enforcement. And 14 we just thought it would be nice to throw in a little 15 breather during the program and talk about how to really 16 avoid you ever having to be back in this office again. 17 So before I do that, I do have the standard 18 disclaimer that I'm sure my peers agree, which is that 19 the opinions I'm going to share with you are my own. I 20 don't speak on behalf of the Commission or the 21 Commissioners. 22 But I want to talk a little about some of the 23 high priority areas and the sorts of enforcement matters 24 that come to our attention that involve newly public 25 companies or emerging companies. 0132 1 The -- you know, not surprisingly, one of the 2 top priorities, certainly for this office, but 3 nationally, has long been financial accounting fraud by 4 public companies. And in this office in particular, 5 we're responsible for Silicon Valley, Seattle, Portland. 6 We have a lot of tech companies, biotech companies that 7 are emerging with their own set of accounting issues. 8 And dating back, I've been here about 15 9 years, and, as far as I can remember, that's always been 10 our number one component of our -- of our docket. And 11 traditionally, it could be a quarter, up to a third of 12 the cases we do in our office involve accounting or 13 disclosure issues with public companies. 14 The piece of good news for the folks in the 15 room is that that is way down. And for the last fiscal 16 year, SEC-wide, only about 15 percent of the enforcement 17 matters we brought involved accounting and disclosure 18 matters for public companies. 19 And I can't tell you exactly why that is. 20 Personally, my belief is that a lot of that has to do 21 with Sarbanes-Oxley. And I know that certainly for 22 those of you in the room and in the industry, there are 23 a lot of concerns with Sarbanes-Oxley and the costs. All 24 I can tell you is that the number of restatements and 25 the number of enforcement matters has gone way down in 0133 1 the last decade. 2 Now, some of that is also just going to be the 3 post-Enron, WorldCom environment where I think companies 4 got a little more careful. I think auditors became much 5 more aggressive, I think boards were more engaged. I 6 think that has no doubt helped quite a bit. 7 I do, unfortunately, have a cynical view that 8 a lot of people have short memories, so I wouldn't be 9 surprised to see that number starting to go back up, 10 certainly as the economy improves. 11 And once again, there's the expectation for 12 companies to reporting -- to be reporting great revenue 13 numbers. I think that's when games start getting played. 14 The piece of bad news I have to share is that 15 to the extent that we do continue to see accounting 16 fraud cases coming out of our office and nationally, a 17 lot of those do tend to be with smaller, newly public 18 companies. I think the quality of internal controls is 19 not quite the same with -- as with an established 20 company. We do see a lot of companies that go public 21 before they necessarily have the mechanisms in place, 22 the internal controls they need to prevent the sort of 23 recurring financial accounting issues we've seen. 24 So some of the classic cases, last day of the 25 quarter, you're not making your numbers, your salesmen 0134 1 are calling all their favorite customers and saying, I 2 know you don't need the product today, maybe six months 3 from now, but let me ship it to you; you don't have to 4 pay, we'll work something out tomorrow, and don't tell 5 our CFO, continues to happens, continues to happens, 6 especially with smaller companies. Tends to happen more 7 frequently I think, at least anecdotally, with companies 8 with offshore operations. 9 So even companies that may have the HQ here in 10 San Jose doing a bang-up job with their internal 11 controls may not have the same focus on what's going on 12 in Singapore. 13 So to the extent there are ongoing financial 14 cases, you know, small companies do need to make sure 15 that they have the appropriate controls, training for 16 their sales staff and finance staff on what is 17 appropriate, what is not. 18 And the top-down pressure always matters. And 19 if you have the CEO and the CFO sending out those 20 e-mails on the last week of the quarter saying, make 21 your numbers or you may be looking for work, you cannot 22 be surprised when games get played to help make those 23 numbers. 24 The -- the other change I've noticed in recent 25 years, in addition to the general decline of these 0135 1 cases, is that to the extent we do continue to see 2 cases, it tends to be less in the revenue area. 3 Historically, it was always revenue. The analyst wanted 4 to see revenue growth, and that's where a lot of the 5 tricks were being played. 6 These days, I think analysts are a little more 7 attuned to that, companies are a little more careful 8 there, but you do continue to see games being played 9 with earnings management. 10 So the inventory numbers, for example, make 11 your margins look better, make your expenses look lower. 12 So you do continue to see that sort of matter. 13 Another area where we have a lot of focus in 14 enforcement is, no surprise, the Foreign Corrupt 15 Practices Act, or the FCPA. This has definitely been an 16 area of huge growth for enforcement. You look back in 17 the past couple decades that that statute has been in 18 existence, and there were very few cases. 19 It's now -- we're actually breaking out 20 statistics on that as a separate area because it's 21 become so prevalent for enforcement interest. About three 22 percent of our enforcement actions last year involved 23 FCPA violations, improper payments to foreign officials 24 in order to secure business. three percent -- 25 MR. GRAHAM: Marc? 0136 1 MR. FAGEL: I'm sorry? 2 MR. GRAHAM: Where there's kind of a hair 3 trigger or are people, in other words, being surprised 4 because they think what they're doing is perfectly 5 normal? I should take that back. It could be normal in 6 that context, but you know what I mean. 7 MR. FAGEL: You know, I'm not sure how to 8 characterize it. You know, as an enforcement attorney, 9 I'm always looking for evidence of scienter. You know, 10 it's not, you know, no one had a clue this was going on, 11 we're shocked. That can still be a violation. 12 But the cases that tend to be more attractive 13 if we're going to have to litigate them are those that 14 have the terrific e-mail where somebody says, don't put 15 this in another e-mail. That happens. There are a lot 16 of e-mails, that is a search term when we are looking at 17 e-mails. 18 So, you know, I can't pretend that there are a 19 significant number of cases where there is obvious 20 knowledge of what's going on at headquarters. You know, 21 you don't -- do not typically have the CFO who says, I'm 22 going to ship you a box of cash so you can get 23 customers. 24 More frequently you'll see very, again, lax 25 controls, where you'll have offshore operations where 0137 1 they are, for example, asking for tens or hundreds of 2 thousands of dollars for a travel budget and no one back 3 in the home office is paying attention that training is 4 being secured for their new customers at Disney World. 5 You know, so, again, it's more, are you not 6 noticing what's going on? Are you not asking the right 7 questions? Why are we spending so much to run the small 8 operation? And coincidentally, we just got a great 9 government contract out of there and we're flying all 10 these people here for a supposed training in Orlando. 11 So, you know, I think that the internal 12 control issue is a significant one. You really do have 13 to be on top of your offshore operations. What are they 14 doing? How are they securing contracts? How are they 15 accounting for their expenses? Are there slush funds 16 being created so that cash or gifts or other rewards can 17 be made to customers or to distributors who are helping 18 to secure the foreign business? 19 And, again, this is the sort of situation 20 where smaller companies are particularly ripe for this 21 abuse because they may not have the controls. They're 22 growing rapidly. There are mergers happening with 23 offshore operations where they may not have the same 24 controls in place to make sure that they're keeping an 25 eye on these sorts of payments. 0138 1 The bigger problem with FCPA, of course, is 2 that it gets tremendous criminal interest. Now, all the 3 securities laws can be enforced criminally, but the FCPA 4 is one area in particular where the Department of 5 Justice finds them hugely interesting. 6 So in a typical SEC investigation into bribery 7 payments, there will most likely be a parallel criminal 8 investigation. We'll work closely with the Department 9 of Justice. And, obviously, the penalties are much 10 greater. It's one thing to be paying a fine to the SEC; 11 it's another thing for your executives to risk 12 incarceration. So the stakes are very high and the 13 costs are very high. 14 Once one of these things arises, you're 15 talking about doing internal investigation and dealing 16 with a government investigation where all the activity 17 is offshore. And once you have paid a large firm to 18 send a large number of partners and associates to China 19 for six months, those bills rack up very, very quickly. 20 So the stakes are very high; very important to 21 make sure that you’ve got internal compliance down and 22 you've got training to prevent this problem before it 23 arises. 24 MR. GRAHAM: How often does incarceration 25 occur? 0139 1 MR. FAGEL: I don't think it happens very 2 often. I think the mere threat of it is enough to avoid 3 the issues. 4 And like I said, it is pretty rare where you 5 will see the scienter evidence arise to a level where 6 you can show a senior executive actually knew or ordered 7 this to happen. But it's not without precedent. 8 And I think one of the bigger threats, it's 9 not so much our authorities, when you're dealing with 10 foreign executives and you're dealing with the foreign 11 government who learns about corruption, and they've got 12 to deal with their own political situation when it comes 13 to light that members of the government are receiving 14 bribes, they may have a different approach to how they 15 deal with executives there. 16 MS. JACOBS: Marc, how do you feel about 17 self-reporting? 18 MR. FAGEL: It's a great question, and 19 something I was exactly going to talk about. I'll talk 20 about it now. 21 MS. JACOBS: Oh, I'm to go -- 22 MR. FAGEL: I think it is -- I think it's 23 essential. And I think it can make all the difference in 24 the world in the outcome of an investigation, when there 25 is a -- is self-reporting. But let me circle back to 0140 1 that and talk about it. It's a great question. 2 Let me hit on two more quick areas on public 3 companies and then turn to a couple short ones on 4 private companies. 5 Two additional areas of interest for public 6 companies, Reg FD, fair disclosure. It's a regulation, 7 been in place about ten years or so. There were a few 8 cases right off the bat when we brought it, then it was 9 quiet. Now there's a bit of a comeback. There have 10 been a few cases. 11 Essentially for those of you not familiar with 12 it, it is a regulation geared at selective disclosure of 13 non-public information to deal with the concern among 14 investors that some companies are reaching out to 15 favored analysts, favored institutional investors, and 16 giving them a bit of a heads-up of some good news or bad 17 news that's not quite out there in the public eye yet. 18 And we continue to see cases. And there have 19 been a number of investigations in the last couple 20 years, some of which have resulted in enforcement 21 actions, where you do see senior executives, you see the 22 CFO going home on a Saturday after reading what the 23 analysts are saying and making one-on-one phone calls to 24 a few analysts to talk them down off their numbers. Some 25 pretty -- some pretty blatant abuses out there. 0141 1 I think when the regulation was first passed, 2 there were concerns that, well, what if -- what if 3 someone has body language during an earnings call and 4 everyone picks up on it, is that unfair? 5 If you look at the cases that have been 6 brought, it's not body language. There are, 7 unfortunately, some corporate executives who will go out 8 there to a hedge fund who has made some general advances 9 in the past and actually pick up the phone and call them 10 and say, you know, your numbers aren't quite right. 11 So the calls I think that we've made have 12 definitely been cases where people would agree has been 13 a violation of selective disclosure. 14 And then the last area that's of perennial 15 interest to us in Enforcement is insider trading. And a 16 lot of these cases are very high profile. The playing 17 field here has really changed in the last few years for 18 the SEC and certainly for the criminal authorities who 19 pay attention. 20 Historically, you'll see basically one-off 21 situations. An executive, a director, an employee who 22 learned something non-public about the company and trades 23 on it or tips. 24 What you've seen changing in the last couple 25 years are large-scale trading rings, systematic trading 0142 1 where you see networks of individuals who provide 2 information, say, to hedge funds reaching out to 3 employees of multiple public companies and 4 systematically obtain non-public information, allowing 5 investors to make millions of dollars. 6 These cases, you know, the repercussions are 7 huge. They have gotten much criminal interest. You 8 have wire taps involved, which really changed the degree 9 and nature of the investigation. Fascinating cases, and 10 not the sort of thing any public company wants to get 11 involved in. 12 Now, the repercussions tend to be for those 13 individuals who are trading and tipping, not necessarily 14 for the company itself. But again, there are huge 15 resource costs. 16 And if the SEC comes calling and next thing 17 you know you've got a senior executive or a member of 18 your board who's wrapped up in an SEC investigation, 19 that can have some serious implications for the future 20 of that individual at your company. 21 So it's definitely, again, worth -- you know, 22 I say it over and over, make sure you got the internal 23 controls in place. Make sure that any non-public 24 information is disseminated only to those who need to 25 know and at the last possible moment to reduce the risk 0143 1 of that leaking out. 2 The other piece of advice I have to give you, 3 especially if you are involved with a newly public 4 company, is the importance of a trading plan. There is 5 an SEC rule that provides for presumption, that if 6 somebody who is trading pursuant to a regular trading 7 plan is not trading on the basis of non-public 8 information. 9 So if your executives have received a large 10 amount of stock, which has value once the company goes 11 public, and get on a trading plan, so that the first day 12 after every earnings announcement every quarter, X 13 percent of the portfolio is liquidated, it makes it very 14 hard for us to get interested. 15 When we see that a CFO made a very large sale 16 the day before an announcement, we will make a phone 17 call and ask about that trade. If we get a copy of the 18 trading plan that says, well, we trade on that day of 19 that month every single month, and we've done that for 20 three years, that's probably the last you'll hear from 21 us. 22 So I can't emphasize about the importance of 23 having a trading plan. And following it. The trading 24 plan doesn't do much good if you don't follow it, or if 25 your trading plan is that I will trade a lot of stock 0144 1 the day after, the day before really good news and -- 2 that's not going to work. 3 But if it's -- if it's a legitimate plan that 4 is followed that's objective and it really takes away 5 the element of trying to capitalize on nonpublic 6 information, it's an excellent idea. 7 And then, finally, I wanted to hit on two 8 issues that come up with companies that are not yet 9 public that tend to be repeat players in our office. 10 Private companies out there financing through 11 private offerings that are playing fast and loose with the facts. You know, the number of fraud cases, it's an 13 ongoing area for our interest when you've got false 14 statements being made in connection with private 15 offerings. 16 Most importantly are representations about how 17 the money is going to be used, the proceeds are going to 18 be used, especially if the money is going into the 19 pockets of the individuals running the company. It very 20 quickly begins to look like misappropriation if there is 21 a disclosure about a certain compensation structure that 22 will be used, but most of the funds, the offering proceeds 23 are going into the pocket of the executives or they're 24 getting large loans that may never be repaid. So 25 representations about what is going to happen with the 0145 1 proceeds of the offering are going to get our attention. 2 We said we repeatedly see instances of playing 3 fast and loose with the background, whether educational, 4 employment background of the principals of the company. 5 Going to attend a seminar one day does not make you a 6 Harvard graduate. 7 You see, you know, overselling of the 8 prospects of the product or service that the company 9 sells; revenue projections that have absolutely no basis 10 in reality. Again, just because you're in telecom space 11 does not mean that you can have the same projections as 12 Apple does for the iPhone. 13 Similarly, talking about your business 14 prospect, your business partnerships has to be honest. 15 And again, you know, the fact that you carry an iPhone 16 does not mean that Apple is a strategic partner of your 17 company. 18 So the things that people will say are crazy. 19 And it's, again, not very difficult for us to disprove a 20 lot of the representations we see. 21 Yes, sir. 22 MR. WALSH: When you mentioned right before 23 about the private placement, do you find a lot of -- 24 more issues with private placement than debt, issuing 25 debt as opposed to friends and family trying to raise 0146 1 some money (inaudible)? 2 MR. FAGEL: I would say that, you know, 3 frankly, where we most frequently see it are in equity 4 securities offerings by small companies, which sometimes 5 start to appear very quickly to be more akin to a Ponzi 6 scheme. So a company that is out there with what they call a 7 private offering, what I think you would do is more 8 public offering. 9 You start having seminars when you reach out 10 to family and friends, and have them share your 11 prospectus with everybody they know. And very quickly, 12 you've got hundreds of people that you've never met 13 sending you money for stock. Those tend to be, you 14 know, where this arises. 15 And again, you know, we are -- there's no 16 secret that we have very limited resources at the 17 Commission. So to get our attention, we really do have 18 to be doing an analysis of: Is this something that 19 we've got the resources, the time, and the manpower to 20 take a look at? 21 So if you're raising a small amount of money 22 from a small number of people, even if there is 23 out-and-out fraud, it may just not be something we're 24 able to deal with. It may result in a referral to a 25 state agency or a district attorney, for example. But 0147 1 the wider, the broader, and the more successful the 2 offering, the more likely we're going to focus on it. 3 And then the last area I touched on are -- and 4 hopefully this isn't something that happens too 5 prevalently with the folks in the room, but companies 6 that choose to go public through a reverse merger with a 7 shell. There are companies that can do that 8 legitimately. 9 I'm not here to disparage whether or not that 10 is an appropriate way of going public, but I do have to 11 say a large number of market manipulation investigations 12 come from what may be at one point legitimate private 13 companies that seek to create liquidity through a 14 reverse merger. 15 And any time the mechanism for going public 16 results in a large proportion of the non-restricted 17 shares being held by a stock promoter or people closely 18 affiliated with the company, I do think that there is a 19 large risk of that company having its stock manipulated 20 for personal gain. 21 And those cases are just -- you know, it's a 22 deluge. They come in day after day, a small company, 23 public through a reverse merger, you see the spam, you 24 see the fax go out, the stock goes from a quarter to 50 25 cents, which doesn't get a lot of our attention, but the 0148 1 stock promoter can make a few million dollars over the 2 course of a weekend through one of these fax campaigns. 3 Turning from these areas to a couple of ways 4 to -- other things for you to be thinking about. One of 5 the major changes in recent years has been the change in 6 our law on whistleblowers under Dodd-Frank. And this 7 is a very new phenomenon where the Commission now has a 8 mechanism and the ability and an incentive to pay cash 9 to individuals who refer information to us that allow us 10 to successfully investigate and prosecute a fraud. 11 This is something that was on the mind of 12 Congress at the time of passage of Dodd-Frank to make 13 sure that individuals had an incentive to come forward 14 with useful information to the SEC and to make sure we 15 had at the staff level an ability to process that and 16 reward that information, which really changes the nature 17 of the game. 18 The number of referrals and complaints we get 19 at the SEC is astronomical. But when there is a price 20 tag and incentive for somebody to give us information 21 that may actually allow them to reap millions of 22 dollars, the numbers can be quite large. 23 The quality of information can go up quite a 24 bit, and the incentives for people who have really 25 meaningful information can go up. You know, I can't 0149 1 tell you how many e-mails we get from somebody saying, 2 my broker is crooked, can you take a look at him? That's 3 of limited use. 4 It's another story if you've got somebody who 5 is a current employee of a company saying, I think our 6 CFO is doing something inappropriate; here's some 7 e-mails, here's some documents I've got, and sign me up 8 because if you successfully investigate this, I'd like 9 to get 10 to 30 percent of any recovery, quality of 10 information is different and the incentive for a current 11 employee to get involved and come to the SEC has really 12 been ratcheted up. 13 It's still a relatively new program. The very 14 first award under the program was made recently. 15 Looking back at some of the areas I mentioned 16 before, you take, for example, a Foreign Corrupt 17 Practices Act case where you may have a $10 million 18 penalty, where we have the ability under Dodd-Frank to 19 give 10 to 30 percent back, you've got somebody with an 20 incentive who can make $3 million by giving us some 21 documents showing us that a bribe has been paid. 22 You know, it's a real incentive maybe for your 23 employees, maybe for your competitors who are feeling a 24 little aggrieved that they did not get the business you 25 got to come to the SEC and say, I've been talking with 0150 1 that distributor, and I can tell you exactly why they 2 made the sale and we didn't; and it's because ABC did 3 XYZ. 4 So we do have regular daily calls coming in 5 from people with valuable information. So, you know, 6 for all of you who are -- who are out there, you do need 7 to be thinking about, what are the employees doing? If 8 they are coming forward to company management or the 9 board with information, that you're taking it seriously, 10 because if you're not, it's pretty likely that they're 11 talking to the SEC. 12 Which brings me to the last issue, which is -- 13 which is something that you raised, which is 14 self-reporting. 15 You know, given that there are more 16 whistle-blowers who are coming to us, the question is, 17 if the information is coming to the company itself as 18 well, what is the company doing? Is the company coming 19 to the SEC? 20 Now, for the past decade or so, we have tried 21 to make it very clear within Enforcement that we do 22 have an expectation for companies to self-report issues 23 to the Division of Enforcement, to work with us to 24 assist in our investigations, and that there are 25 material differences in the results of any investigation 0151 1 depending on the level of cooperation that we receive 2 from the company. 3 So, you know, a company that comes -- and this 4 happens all the time. You know, they'll call me or 5 they'll call our head of Enforcement and say, our 6 auditors came across something unusual, we're conducting 7 an internal investigation, we would like to come to your 8 office and share the information, share some documents, 9 talk about what we learn through our interviews of some 10 of our employees. That is something that is looked upon 11 pretty favorably. 12 A company that decides to wait to see how it 13 works out, and the first we hear of it is because a 14 whistleblower comes and calls us up and says, you know, 15 this whole thing is going on with the company and you 16 don't know about it or we read about it in the paper or 17 the company announces a restatement, which is news to 18 us, we're already wondering, is this company going to 19 ultimately want to do the right thing when they weren't 20 even talking to us about it? 21 So it is very important for companies to think 22 seriously about reaching out to Enforcement, giving us a 23 heads-up and sharing information. 24 And, you know, I know that there's a serious 25 calculation among defense counsel about whether or not 0152 1 to do that. 2 I come back to what I said earlier about our 3 limited resources. If a company calls me up and says, 4 we've got an issue, we're taking a look at it, can we 5 come in in a month or two when we're done with our 6 internal investigation and share the information, it's 7 going to mean I can sit back and not be sending out 8 subpoenas, not be forcing my staff to cut up an 9 otherwise busy day to run out and start talking to 10 witnesses. That is good for me and would be something 11 we'd want to be thinking about later on in deciding what 12 to do with a company if there is a problem. 13 If it turns out there is no problem and the 14 company comes and we've got a basis to believe that 15 they're shooting straight, sharing information, and it 16 turns out that there's nothing there of interest, we 17 probably are going to go away. We've got better things 18 to do. I've got a million other cases that we can be 19 investigating. 20 So I think there's a perception of a major 21 downside of fronting the issue for us, but if it turns 22 out to be nothing, we've got other things to do; if it 23 turns out to be something, I think the company benefits 24 by giving us a heads-up and working with us. 25 I think to the extent there's a perception 0153 1 that if the company doesn't share the information and 2 hopes for the best it's going to work out, I don't think 3 that's right. If we read about a restatement and the 4 company is saying, well, send us subpoenas and you'll 5 learn what you learn, we're going to send those 6 subpoenas. You may, you know, have about 30 executives 7 spending, you know, a lot of days in this room being 8 questioned because we don't know what's going on and 9 we're trying to figure out what happened. We're going 10 to be asking for an awful lot of documents because we 11 need to figure out for ourselves what went wrong. 12 In contrast, if independent counsel, forensic 13 experts hired by the company come in, make a 14 presentation to us, and say, here's what we've looked 15 at, here's five individuals who you need to talk to, 16 these are the top people involved. These five people 17 know nothing, we've talked to them. Here are the key 18 documents that are going to help you make a decision, 19 it's going to allow us to narrow our investigation. 20 Again, we don't have the resources or the 21 inclination to look under every rock. If we can 22 understand from the company and believe we're getting 23 fair information on what might be out there, we've got 24 every incentive in the world to focus our investigation, 25 to wrap things up quickly, and then to look favorably 0154 1 about the company when we're trying to decide what -- 2 how to resolve it. 3 So that's what -- what I wanted to share with 4 all of you. Happy to take any questions in our 5 remaining time. 6 MS. JACOBS: I have one question. 7 MR. FAGEL: Sure. 8 MS. JACOBS: I'm sure I'll get some of the 9 specifics wrong, because it's not the criminal activity 10 thing, but like when there's a question and we get 11 comment, what are they called, comment letters or 12 something about our filings or perhaps there was some 13 kind of activity with trading and you get a FINRA letter 14 that says, what do you know, and what was everybody 15 doing on March 6th? That kind of a letter. 16 How come you answer everything, and then you 17 don't get a response back? And you're supposed to 18 believe that if the file is sort of divisible by two, 19 it's over. Do you know what I mean? Or we don't get a 20 response back from the Exchange that says, oh, we're 21 okay with what y'all did on March 6th, and it's over. In 22 other words, you never seem to get case-closed letters. 23 MR. FAGEL: Yeah. No, I understand what 24 you're saying. There's a few different issues wrapped 25 up there. 0155 1 In terms of FINRA, you know, when there is an 2 insider trading issue, the exchanges are incredibly 3 sophisticated. So they've got bells and whistles that 4 go off anytime there's an announcement and significant 5 trading in the days leading up to that. So it would not 6 be unusual to get a letter from the exchange. 7 MR. JACOBS: Right. 8 MR. FAGEL: You know, NASDAQ will send a 9 letter saying, can you tell us who was involved in this 10 announcement? You know, I can't tell you what their 11 practice is and why they do or don't respond to what 12 happens afterwards to the extent that results in a 13 referral from the exchange to us, which is typically 14 what will happen. 15 If we begin investigating and talk to you, it is 16 the practice, standard practice of the Division of 17 Enforcement that we complete -- when we complete our 18 investigation, we send a closing letter. That should be 19 done as a matter of course. 20 It is the instruction to my staff that when we 21 are done, you send a closing letter and say, we're done, 22 and we're not making any recommendation to the 23 Commission that enforcement be brought. 24 MS. JACOBS: Is that unique to y'all out here? 25 MR. FAGEL: No. That is the policy of the 0156 1 Division of Enforcement. 2 There are exceptions. If there is, for 3 example, criminal interest or if there are different 4 matters that are related and we're concerned if we send 5 this closing letter to you and you make it public and it 6 creates perception, that everything has gone away. 7 So there's exceptions, but for the most part 8 that is the practice. 9 I do get this question periodically from 10 defense counsel who say, well, we haven't heard from 11 you. You can call. And, you know, I can't tell you how 12 many times I hear, well, I'm afraid if I call, I'll 13 remind you to take a look at this investigation. 14 My job is to manage what happens in my office. 15 We have multiple levels of management. I get -- have 16 quarterly calls with Rob Khuzami, the Director of 17 Enforcement in Washington, to go over our docket. 18 We haven't forgotten about the investigation. 19 You're not going to remind us, oh, yeah, that case, we 20 need to sue this company. 21 So it's not that hard to pick up and say -- 22 and a lot of people do it, and say, you know, we haven't 23 heard from you in some time, what's going on? Sometimes 24 they'll say, you know, that slipped through the cracks, 25 we're done. Sometimes we'll say, it's still going on. 0157 1 Sometimes, look, you get a difficult matter 2 and it can take months and months for us to decide how 3 to resolve it, to work through the Divisions in D.C. We 4 can't bring any Enforcement action without the five 5 Commissioners in Washington signing off. That process 6 can take some time, especially for something that's 7 novel or controversial. 8 So sometimes the answer is, I can't tell you 9 what's going on, but I'll get back to you. But if it's 10 really we're done, we'll tell you. That is the policy. 11 In terms of a letter to Corporation Finance, I 12 can't -- I do not know what the process is for closing 13 those down. 14 MR. NALLENGARA: We do the same thing. Our 15 policy is to send a letter saying that we're done. And 16 if we don't, you should -- you should call Marc too. 17 I'm just kidding. 18 MS. GREENE: On a standard comment letter like 19 something on a question on filing, isn't there -- and we 20 haven't gotten one in a really long time, no big deal, 21 but I think it says, unless -- once you respond, unless 22 you hear from us, you assume -- 23 MR. NALLENGARA: I think -- 24 MS. GREENE: Is that old? 25 MR. NALLENGARA: Yeah, I think that's old. 0158 1 You shouldn't be getting that. 2 MS. GREENE: I don't know how long it's been. 3 MS. ZEPRALKA: We send a “no further comments” letter. 4 MR. FAGEL: Any other questions I can answer? 5 MR. DENNIS: What's your opinion of the crowd 6 funding? 7 MR. FAGEL: What's my opinion of the crowd 8 funding? Well, I leave it to the regulatory folks to 9 make those decisions. I only have to clean up the mess 10 when something goes awry. 11 Okay. I can't weigh in on that itself. What 12 I can tell you is the Enforcement staff here gets very 13 busy anytime it is easier for smaller entities and 14 individuals to raise money. And that's the way it 15 works. The more -- I do see that the regulatory 16 burdens, as expensive and onerous as they may sometimes 17 be, they minimize fraud. So it's a trade-off that the 18 industry has to make and that the regulators have to 19 make at what -- you know, what's the cost versus what's 20 the fraud prevention? 21 You know, any time that there is more ability 22 to, you know, widen the net of how many people can be 23 out there raising money for more people, I'm going to 24 get busy with fraud cases. And I can't tell you how 25 many operators are already out there using the word 0159 1 "crowdfunding" in their offerings of what are probably 2 outright frauds or Ponzi schemes. 3 So, you know, I think that there's some risk 4 in there. You know, does it help small businesses? You 5 know, that's not for me to say in the equation that I 6 get into, but there are trade-offs involved. And I 7 think it is important to recognize the trade-offs that 8 it is going to likely result in some problems. 9 MR. NALLENGARA: Thank you, Marc. 10 MR. FAGEL: Thank you. 11 MR. GRAHAM: So that gives us five minutes. 12 MR. NALLENGARA: Give people time to check 13 back home. Meet in ten -- no, no, five. 14 MR. GRAHAM: It's a negotiation. Okay. Ten 15 minutes. 16 (A brief recess was taken.) 17 MR. GRAHAM: Let's get back together with the 18 afternoon session. As you know, this afternoon we are 19 talking about the disclosure rules of smaller companies 20 and the issue of scaling. And we've put together a panel 21 for this afternoon to give us some background. 22 And their full biographies are in the 23 materials that you've received earlier. Let me just 24 kind of run down briefly who you will be hearing from. 25 First is Steve Bochner sitting next to Lona. 0160 1 He's a partner at Wilson Sonsini with more than 30 years 2 of experience practicing corporate and securities law. 3 From 2009 to 2012, Steve worked as the firm's 4 chief executive officer, and is currently a member of 5 its board of directors. 6 He also recently served on the IPO Task 7 Force, whose recommendations served as the basis for the 8 IPO-related provisions of the JOBS Act. 9 From 1996 to 2011, Steve served on the NASDAQ 10 Listing and Hearing Review Council, and he also served 11 on the California Department of Corporation and 12 Securities Regulation Advisory Committee. 13 Steve also -- Steve was also a member of the 14 SEC's previous Advisory Committee on Smaller Public 15 Companies that was formed in 2005. 16 Steve, welcome. 17 Jeff Schwartz is an associate who -- we kind 18 of skipped over you. I see "Bobby" in the notes. Do 19 you go by Bobby? 20 MR. BARTLETT: I have never been able to shake 21 it. 22 MR. GRAHAM: Well, we just skipped right over 23 you, Bobby. 24 And finishing up with Jeff Schwartz, he is an 25 Associate Professor at the University of Utah, S.J. -- 0161 1 the S.J. Quinney College of Law. He teaches business 2 organizations and corporate finance, and his research 3 centers on securities law, investment-management 4 regulation, and retirement policy. 5 Prior to joining the faculty of University of 6 Utah, Jeff taught and practiced law in Southern 7 California. 8 In practice, he served both as in-house 9 counsel and as a corporate attorney for Munger Tolles 10 where he represented clients regarding mergers and 11 acquisitions, corporate governance matters, and 12 securities law compliance. So Jeff. 13 Now back to Bobby. Robert Bartlett is a 14 Professor of Law at Berkeley. His primary research -- 15 his primary research interests focus on the intersection 16 of finance and business law, and he teaches in the areas 17 of securities regulation, corporate finance, and 18 contracts. 19 He also serves as a member of the faculty for 20 the Berkeley Center on Law, Business and the Economy. 21 So that's -- is that a journal? 22 MR. BARTLETT: No, it's a center at Berkeley. 23 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. 24 MR. BARTLETT: Actually, Steve's there as 25 well. 0162 1 (Outside noise.) 2 MR. GRAHAM: What is that noise? 3 Okay. Let's see. And you're an editor of 4 Berkeley's -- of Berkeley's VC Research Network. 5 Bobby previously worked as a corporate 6 associate at Gunderson. 7 So that is our expert panel, and looking 8 forward to hearing what you have to say about scaling, 9 if we can hear you through the scatter. 10 Who are we starting with? 11 MR. BOCHNER: Starting with me. Great to be 12 here. Sitting awfully tall. Unusual for me. So it's 13 really a pleasure, a privilege to be here today. It's 14 hard to believe that our -- I was on the SEC Advisory 15 Committee seven years ago. And Leroy was on that 16 committee, and there was another member who -- Richard 17 Brown, who's in the audience today. It was a great 18 experience. And many of our recommendations did 19 translate into -- directly and indirectly into real 20 (inaudible) form. 21 So we found that the staff took the 22 recommendations very seriously, and we felt like we made 23 an impact. So I encourage you to take advantage of this 24 opportunity. 25 Some of the things that we focused on in those 0163 1 days was -- SOX was pretty fresh, and so we spent an 2 inordinate amount of time on 404. And I think it had 3 some role, Leroy, in actually getting the auditing 4 standard changed. I think we can take some credit for 5 that. 6 Other things like integrating S-B into 7 Regulation S-K, which got rid of the stigma of using 8 small reporting rules and other types of scaled 9 disclosure. 10 So I think you can make a real impact. 11 And so some of the dialogue really hasn't 12 changed a lot from those days. But 404 just sucked all 13 of the oxygen out of the room. It seemed for most of 14 those sessions, we did spend a fair amount of time on 15 scaled disclosure. And obviously that continues to be an 16 issue, how to make the markets, how to make securities 17 regulation achieve that very delicate balance between 18 investor protection and capital raising. 19 So we struggled in those days to try to find 20 it. I'm sure you're struggling to try to find that 21 balance as well. 22 I'd like to start my remarks with making a 23 connection between the prior panel and the scaled 24 disclosure. I do think market structure is directly 25 related to the scaled disclosure issue. I'll talk a 0164 1 little bit more about that in a moment. 2 I think we're at a really important juncture 3 here, and I feel that even more so than what we've 4 learned since. And the reason I think we're at a unique 5 juncture, we have a confluence of changes in 6 technology, market pressures, foreign competition, all 7 kind of coming together and I think creating a cocktail 8 of, you know, whether you call it innovation or a 9 thought process, that's really challenging what has up 10 to now been a fairly rigid structure, you know, for 80 11 years since -- almost 80 years since the 12 Securities Act of 1933 was adopted that sort of envisioned 13 a two-tier world: a paper-based world of purely private 14 placements, you know, with some exception. And then 15 full-blown Sarbanes-Oxley, Dodd-Frank compliant world, 16 a public world. 17 And I think what you're seeing now is that 18 paradigm being challenged, being challenged for a number 19 of reasons. But one of those is that I think the 20 confluence of increased regulation, some of the trading 21 issues we've heard about this morning, and we're going to 22 hear about later on today. Investor expectations has 23 created what I call a gap in the capital market. I 24 think this gap is tangible. And you in fact have been 25 talking about it today. It's a gap that's characterized 0165 1 by how long it takes to get a company public. 2 In my world, which is kind of Silicon Valley 3 technology companies, you got a hundred million in 4 revenue now and have market caps that are approaching a 5 billion dollars. We really don't have a viable 6 chance -- absent some hyper-growth story perhaps, we 7 really don't have a viable chance of getting Goldman 8 Sachs, J.P. Morgan to get interested enough to expose 9 you as an IPO candidate to a client base and -- their 10 customer base. 11 This -- this gap that's developed between the 12 private finance world, the seed round, Series A, B, C, 13 D, and then going public, which used to occur over five years 14 and used to occur when companies noted a $30 million 15 revenue range. If you go back and look at Cisco and 16 Apple and Microsoft's prospectus, they really could not 17 go public today because they just don't have the scale 18 to support the expense structure that frankly investors 19 would expect through a company. 20 And this gap -- some aspects of this gap I 21 think are good things. You know, I think to the extent 22 that we've improved investor protection with -- with 23 listing standards and regulation/government reform, some 24 of that is quite good for the retail investors I 25 suppose. 0166 1 But what it's done in that gap, that move from 2 five years to ten years, that move from 30 million in 3 revenue to a hundred million in revenue, that increased 4 expense structure to support a public company, is it's 5 created capital raising and liquidity challenges in the 6 end. And that's, I think, a lot of what we're talking 7 about and saying. 8 As we talk about market structure and talk 9 about scaling regulation, I think we're really zeroing 10 in on that gap. And that gap is important because it 11 turns then to foreign competitiveness, growth -- 12 economic growth, job creation, and the like. 13 The '33 Act construct, as I mentioned a bit 14 ago, is looking increasingly out of date. You can 15 see -- you can see that out-of-date aspect to it, not 16 only in the size of the companies that are going public 17 today, but just in the use of technology. 18 The idea that -- that information outflows 19 instantaneously, versus 1933 when you actually had -- 20 the rules were designed for paper-based, or paper changed 21 hands. Investors can get information instantly. The 22 idea that the prospectus was the sole disclosure 23 document created a regulatory environment around this 24 sort of sacrosanct piece of paper that we use to audit 25 or offer securities. 0167 1 Now that's coming under a lot of pressure as 2 investors are bombarded with all sorts of information, 3 and they can get it instantaneously. 4 Professor Schwartz, whose paper I read, I 5 think shares these observations about the outmoded 6 nature of our market structure. I think there's only 7 going to be increased pressure on our market structures 8 as the need for -- I don't think this gap is going to go 9 away. We may be able to ameliorate it with some reduced 10 disclosure and so on. But I think when the retail 11 investors dispose, I think it's going to be very hard to 12 submit and grow back a lot of reforms. 13 So what I'm intrigued about, is there -- is 14 this two-tiered market structure the best that we can 15 do? Is that construct from 1933 really the right 16 construct, or are some of these new models that we're 17 seeing fill this gap that I described, whether it's, you 18 know, the SecondMarket/Sharespost providing liquidity 19 or AngelList providing capital raising capabilities, 20 should that be the solution as opposed to sort of 21 arguing about when we roll back SOX, what's the level of 22 disclosure and so on? Can we be more innovative with 23 different types of market structures that I think are 24 very much in the vein of scaled disclosure? Scale 25 disclosure by sort of taking the public company world 0168 1 and trying to roll back disclosures based upon the size 2 of the company. 3 But that always presents a dilemma because 4 those are the -- the smaller companies are the riskiest 5 companies. So if you roll back disclosures -- and this 6 is some of the dialogue we had in our '05, '06 SEC 7 Advisory Committee -- roll back disclosures for those who 8 compromise investor protection, the risk is kind of 9 cumbersome. So that's the dilemma. 10 Whereas a market structure sort of solution 11 where you tier access to different markets based upon 12 the type of investor so that you -- investors that don't 13 need registration-level protection perhaps have access 14 to different kinds of markets maybe with different tick 15 sizes and some of the other innovations that all of you 16 are talking about, I think that's what -- that's what 17 intrigues me. 18 So I encourage you to think about scaled 19 disclosure and recommendations in both contexts, both -- 20 you know, are there things -- is there low-hanging fruit 21 in terms of current securities regulatory environment 22 disclosure requirements and audit standards that really 23 are overkill and not necessary for investor protection, 24 kind of relook at that balancing between capital-raising 25 investor protection, but also take a look at whether the 0169 1 actual structure of our market, this two-tiered world, 2 this two-tiered regulatory environment, I might call it 3 with some license, because obviously there's SEC rules 4 that do different things. Reg A might be a good 5 example. 6 But by and large, that's kind of how -- you 7 know, that's how the world has worked. Private 8 placements, public offerings, those worlds have gotten 9 further apart, it's created this gap in the middle, all 10 this pressure. And I think that's a big reason why 11 you're here today. 12 Some of the changes that we need to bring 13 about these kinds of market structure innovations we 14 recommended in 2006. And some of them have been 15 addressed at the SEC Small Business Forum over the years 16 or in the report. I remember that; I presided over 17 that. 18 And some of them are -- have become law and 19 are about to become law under the JOBS Act. And 20 examples of that are Section 12(g) relief, the 500 shareholder 21 relief, facilitating new methods of solicitation using 22 modern technologies. 23 Knocking on doors on Sandhill Road is one way 24 to find investors, but we have -- if we can find 25 people spouses on the Internet, can't we hook up more 0170 1 efficiently investors and companies in some way that 2 doesn't compromise investor protection? 3 Professor Schwartz points out in his paper 4 additional solutions should be scaled. I mean, the size 5 of the issuer, the investor protection. And that 6 would -- I think that would not only help with capital 7 formation and job creation, but also help our foreign 8 competitiveness against markets, which still have yet, I 9 think, to be a real threat to our domestic markets here. 10 But I don't think that's going to last for a 11 decade or two decades. I think more markets are 12 going to compete for listings or certain listings, 13 companies in those areas. I think they've done that 14 successfully. 15 Where they have been less successful is 16 competing for listings with, you know, the mainstream 17 U.S. venture backed high profile issuer. We've managed to 18 hang on to those, but I don't think we can take that for 19 granted. 20 You know, I think, as is the case with other 21 industries, the U.S. should innovate their market 22 structure, the same way it is innovative with respect to 23 information technologies and life sciences. 24 So I've been pontificating a bit, but I do 25 have some specific recommendations about things that you 0171 1 can do. 2 Before I go to those, let me -- let me just 3 talk about an example of a new kind of market structure, 4 which is AngelList. And if you haven't seen AngelList, 5 it's an online marketplace where you have to get -- you 6 have to prove you're an accredited investor, and 7 companies can list matches, investors, and companies. 8 And we -- I think just a couple of days ago we 9 announced in conjunction with AngelList that we are -- 10 that they put up a new portion of their website where 11 startups can go and basically close a financing on an 12 automated basis using documents online. And we -- and 13 we committed that for clients we then take on -- we'll 14 do that part of the closing process for free. 15 So you can see the, you know, the amazing 16 change over just a decade ago where you can go -- where 17 you go on a website, hopefully get access to investors 18 that are interested, have a term sheet negotiated, have 19 financing documents created. And basically lawyers who 20 author them still need to be involved in things like 21 disclosure schedules and organization and securities law 22 for clients. But the basic fundamentals of generating a 23 term sheet and generating a document and finding 24 investments are automated, and I think that's really 25 cool. 0172 1 And I think there is -- excuse me. I think 2 there's more of that to come. And I think SecondMarket 3 and Sharespost will reflect that innovation with respect 4 to liquidity. 5 Several years ago I gave a series of talks on 6 what kinds of regulatory changes would be necessary to 7 bring about innovation with respect to these alternative 8 markets. And I said there were four changes which need 9 to be made in order to have kind of this gap filled with 10 a different kind of market structure. 11 I said one was a change to the 500 shareholder 12 test. Because if you had a robust alternative market, 13 as soon as you got the 500 shareholder, you go public, 14 you know, nobody was going to do that. You weren't 15 going to have meaningful liquidity. So I said there 16 needed to be some relief to allow companies to be able 17 to operate in that segment without fear of having to 18 register. 19 I said secondly there needed to be some 20 changes to the general solicitation provisions to use 21 modern technologies and access a broader swath of 22 investors using technology. 23 Thirdly, I suggested that federal preemption 24 of Blue Sky laws was necessary because Blue Sky amounted 25 to a 50-state Blue Sky compliance check. And to do 0173 1 compliance work, using a private company is expensive 2 and burdensome. 3 And lastly, I said that you needed to provide 4 better liquidity through 144 amendment. 5 So I said, if you could imagine all those 6 things being done, you could envision a different kind 7 of -- kind of market structure, perhaps with different 8 governance standards and listing requirements that could 9 provide some amount of liquidity, some amount of capital 10 raising, and be accessible by investors, that, from a 11 regulatory point of view, whether it's accredited 12 investors or some higher standard, are investors that 13 are deemed not to need registration’s 14 protection. So sort of a scaled market approach. 15 So interestingly, the first two have actually 16 been accomplished during the process being accomplished 17 by the JOBS Act. You have 12(g) relief under the JOBS 18 Act. And the SEC, as Lona indicated this morning, just 19 published a proposal regarding the general solicitation 20 provision. I'll comment on that in a moment. 21 I think that the two other changes are ones 22 that I hope you think about. 23 One is -- one is 144 change. And let me 24 explain it this way: Under Rule 506, if I'm an issuer, 25 I can sell stock to an accredited investor without 0174 1 registration. And let's say that investor is Sequoia 2 Capital, a well-known venture capital fund. Sequoia 3 Capital, though, if it wants to sell those shares and 4 rely on an SEC safe harbor, it has to have a one-year 5 holding period, even if it's selling those shares to 6 Kleiner Perkins. And the reason that that's an issue 7 is that creates stiction. If you imagine an efficient 8 middle market -- actually, it's stiction, which I 9 believe is unnecessary. 10 In other words, if an issuer can tell -- sell 11 to Sequoia without registration because Sequoia meets 12 whatever standards are put into place for investors who 13 don't need registration-level protection, why does 14 Sequoia have to endure a one-year holding period to sell 15 to another similarly situated investor? I would argue 16 you don't need that. There's no investor protection 17 mandate in that one-year holding period as long as the 18 transferee meets the same standards as are required when 19 that first investor parts with their money. 20 So I think what that would do -- there is a 21 "if we build it will they come" aspect to this. That 22 may be above my pay grade because it really relates to 23 our institutional investors in the market, you know. But 24 early indications if you look at AngelList are -- I 25 think are certainly intriguing in that regard. 0175 1 MR. WALSH: Do you know the rationale for that 2 decision years ago? 3 MR. BOCHNER: What's that? 4 MR. WALSH: The one-year hold. 5 MR. BOCHNER: Yeah, there's a good rationale 6 for it. And Lona can chime in here, too. 7 But the thinking is that if you have -- if you 8 go through -- from a regulatory point of view, if you 9 require a company to file a registration statement, you 10 know, that exposes retail investors. If you have a 11 private placement, you don't have to do that with 12 certain standards that you put in place like accredited 13 investors. 14 But yet, if accredited -- if you are an 15 issuer, I can sell to an accredited investor, and the 16 accredited investor can turn around and distribute the 17 shares publicly to a bunch of non-accredited investors 18 without registration, then that’s just really an end-run 19 around the registration requirement. 20 So it was put in place for a good reason. 21 It's just that I think, you know, this -- you know, the 22 idea of this sort of secondary market, this middle 23 market was not really in existence then. 24 So I think we now need to expand that thinking 25 to say, well, trans -- we don't need a one-year holding 0176 1 period if the transferee meets whatever standards we set 2 for not needing registration level protection. So -- 3 MS. SMITH: Steve, your standard of time that 4 they're warranting, you know, that there's a demand for 5 accredited investors wanting to pick up that 6 (inaudible). 7 MR. BOCHNER: Karen, well, you're -- given 8 your background, you probably have more expertise on 9 this than I do, but I think you suffered from the other 10 side of that in your prior role because I think 11 there's -- the answer is, from my experience, that 12 companies do want that, but they want to control it. 13 And so I think a lot of, what I know you had to deal 14 with in your prior life was sort of the bad side of 15 that, shares getting out, being out of control, worrying 16 about the 500 shareholder test, worrying about the 17 company liability. 18 So I think that the standards aren't in place 19 yet, but I think the issuers would like to facilitate 20 that liquidity, but control it. 21 MS. SMITH: Because the issue we had 22 (inaudible) -- 23 MR. LAPORTE: Could you make sure to 24 speak into the microphone, please? 25 MS. SMITH: Sorry. 0177 1 I mean, I think we have the issue of the 2 example of Sequoia wanting to sell to Kleiner, it was 3 employee A wanting to sell shares to some random person 4 to offset the market. I guess I'm just curious 5 (inaudible). 6 MR. NALLENGARA: Yeah. It's a fair question 7 whether Sequoia can sell it through some trading 8 facility, not sell it through another private -- I mean, 9 their -- your question is whether they -- whether they 10 can freely trade the securities rather than rely on 11 other private placements to sell the securities. So, 12 you know, Kleiner -- Sequoia sells to Kleiner, the 13 problem is you couldn't sell it, you couldn't put it in 14 newspaper ads and sell the securities you bought. 15 MR. BOCHNER: Oh, correct, yeah. 16 MR. NALLENGARA: What you're suggesting is 17 someone taking advantage of some -- someone being able 18 to take advantage of AngelList or some list like that to 19 be able to sell the securities. 20 MR. BOCHNER: So if AngelList -- if AngelList, 21 not to pick on them. You imagine some market structure 22 that's a credible market structure, maybe it has 23 listing -- some listing standards, maybe some governance 24 standards, but well below the Sarbanes-Oxley, Dodd-Frank 25 level. It would be a place where you could go to raise 0178 1 capital, like AngelList is facilitating today. And 2 hopefully there is going to become a meaningful middle 3 market, would allow some -- some liquidity. 4 And if I were saying that there would be an 5 issuer control liquidity, I think the issuer should have 6 control have to (inaudible) to the board. 7 But to the extent that you had a one-year 8 holding period existing today, so you actually had to 9 buy it, that would create a lot of inefficiency. But 10 there's -- you know, there are other ways to trade 11 securities like the four one and a half exemption, but there's 12 sort of a race to the bottom. 13 You're smiling, because you're well aware of 14 that. 15 So we do need -- I think we do need either -- 16 in order to -- if you like the idea of a different 17 market structure and you like the idea of having some 18 liquidity in that market structure, then a one-year 19 holding period doesn't make sense. As long as the buyer 20 of that is also on that -- on that marketplace that only 21 allows investors that don't need registration protection 22 and is done in a way that the issuer has decided to take 23 advantage of. So the issuer is always going to say, I'm 24 either going to list there, I'm not going to list there. 25 I'll allow my shares to be traded there. 0179 1 And certainly, as you point out, Karen, I 2 think a lot of the liquidity strains are coming from 3 employees who have worked for seven years and they want 4 to buy a house or they have other health needs or 5 whatever, and yet the company can't go public yet. It 6 doesn't meet this ever increasing threshold to go 7 public. I think a lot of stress and strain, frankly, I 8 think a lot of these business models are propped up to 9 deal with that. 10 And I think your prior employer is just sort 11 of one of the very early companies that started -- that 12 had gotten into -- that was kind of dealing with an 13 environment that was equipping it with all sorts of 14 issues. And some of these, like the shareholder test, 15 help ameliorate to some degree. 16 So I'll hurry up so I'm not taking too much 17 time away from these other presentations. 18 So the first of my recommendations are to 19 consider both whether the 144 one-year holding period 20 makes sense if the transferee meets certain standards. 21 And the second is federal preemption with respect to 22 that secondary transfer, some kind of a 50-state Blue 23 Sky. 24 Secondly, and this is a little long-term, I 25 think the 500 shareholder relief is welcome. There's 0180 1 one little tweak that I'm kind of unhappy with, which is 2 that while employees are excluded from the -- now the 3 2,000 shareholder count, accredited investors aren't. 4 And I would argue that if an accredited investor can buy 5 shares from an issuer without registration, why should 6 just a sheer number of them give rise to the need for 7 registration under the '34 Act? 8 So I think in addition to employees being 9 excluded from the account -- 2,000 shareholder count, 10 which they are now under the JOBS Act, in theory, that 11 the protections aren't needed because these are 12 compensatory transactions, not capital raising 13 transactions. I think the same theory should apply to 14 investors that are determined under other SEC rules not 15 to meet registration-level protection. So just 16 adding -- adding the numbers shouldn't give rise to 17 that. 18 So my second recommendation, and I think this 19 is longer term, but would be to exclude accredited 20 investors from the count. 21 You know, I have a third recommendation, which 22 is not really in the scaled disclosure area, but it 23 relates to Rule 506. Lona heard me make it on a webcast 24 the other day. But I think the SEC's proposed rule 25 under the general solicitation provisions is too broad. 0181 1 I was -- as Steve mentioned, I was a member of the IPO 2 Task Force that helped come up with some of the ideas 3 behind the JOBS Act, and general solicitation was one of 4 them. 5 But I certainly don't want to see late night 6 TV ads, newspaper ads, Internet, you know, commercials, 7 you know, blasting, hawking stock. I think that's bad for 8 the markets. I think it's bad from a regulatory point 9 of view. And I think it's bad for the kind of reforms 10 we're talking about here. 11 And it -- you know, the question is whether 12 the SEC has the authority under the JOBS Act to 13 constrain that. I actually think they do. I think 14 it's -- I think even though the bill says eliminate the 15 general solicitation provisions, I don't think that 16 means that the SEC can't regulate as to how that 17 solicitation occurs. And I think the SEC's experts in 18 these areas will have to decide whether or not I'm right 19 about that. 20 But I think SEC rules like 134 and 135 provide 21 a really good template for when the retail investor is 22 exposed, you know, how a company should be permitted to 23 offer stock in newspapers and TV and ads. That's my 24 third recommendation., 25 My fourth does finally -- I should get to scaled 0182 1 disclosure. We took a hard look at this. We -- in '05 2 and '06 -- we suggested that many of the small business 3 reforms get made accessible to a broad swath of smaller 4 public companies. And these are things like a reduced 5 business section, reduced MD&A, reduced market risk 6 disclosure, reduced executive compensation provisions. 7 Some of these are addressed in the JOBS Act. 8 I would encourage you to look at the 9 threshold, to read it, that was established as a result 10 of our work in those days, which is a smaller reporting 11 company, $75 million in market cap, which is not very 12 meaningful. You get a company public with that kind of 13 market cap and ask yourselves whether that threshold 14 ought to be raised with some meaningful number. 15 You know, back in '06 we were -- I haven't 16 updated this, but I think we were given the information 17 by the SEC Office of Economic Analysis, which said that 18 companies above $787 million in market capitalization 19 represented basically 94 percent of U.S. market 20 capitalization, meaning that companies below that market 21 cap are very unlikely to result in systemic risk. You 22 know, you're just not having that much of a market cap 23 affected. 24 And you kind of use that as a theory to say, 25 well, if that's the case, there's no real systemic risk, 0183 1 which is sort of -- those were in those days 2 Sarbanes-Oxley and Dodd-Frank, let's see if we can't do 3 some things to make the disclosure burdens lessen. So 4 take a look at the scaled disclosure, the size, and see 5 if there's other low-hanging fruit out there. 6 And then I have one more recommendation. And 7 I have a prop for this recommendation, actually, that 8 Lona took a peek at. 9 This is my prop. And this is -- this is -- I 10 had printed out a client's filings. 11 Anybody guess how many years of SEC filings 12 this is for my client? 13 PARTICIPANT: One. 14 MR. BOCHNER: One year. And this is a -- 15 there's a proxy statement, 10-Qs, and one 10-K. And 16 back in '05, '06 we actually recommended that EDGAR be 17 reformed and looked at. 18 EDGAR, you know, is a -- if you go on EDGAR 19 today, what you get is sort of a chronological listing 20 of filings. So 10-Q, 10-K, bunch of forms, proxy, 8-K. 21 And it's very hard to find stuff. You know, 22 where's the current business section, where is -- I 23 mean, I couldn't -- if you ask me, and I kind of read 24 this stuff for a living, tell me what the CEO made last 25 year, I can sort of find it, but it would take me a 0184 1 while. I have to know what document to go in. 2 And there's a lot of repetition in here. 3 There are financial statement footnotes that repeat over 4 and over and over. And it takes a lot of work, lawyers 5 reviewing it, accountants reviewing it. 6 And I would argue that, even if this is 7 written in plain English, this really isn't plain 8 English. When something gets this big, it's not plain 9 English. It's just hard to find. 10 So I think that -- there was an SEC initiative 11 many years ago called the 21st Century Disclosure 12 Initiative. I think it generated some ridicule to call it 13 that. But I actually think it proposed a really 14 interesting idea, which is to sort of do away with the 15 idea of the serial chronological list of filings. 16 And when a company goes public, they file a 17 company registration. That's their document. That's a 18 disclosure document. And every time a quarter occurs or 19 year occurs, you update that document, and you can see 20 where it got updated. So there's one static document. 21 As the business section, as the current comp, you can go 22 back and I think with technology figure out what the 23 company -- what changes had gotten made. But basically 24 there's one place to look. 25 And I think it would make -- I think it would 0185 1 reduce costs, and I think it would make the ability of 2 investors to ferret out information much, much better 3 and can actually help the rest of us. 4 So, again, thanks for having me here today, 5 and I really look forward to reading your 6 recommendations. 7 MR. GRAHAM: Thank you, Steve. 8 Who's next? Let's go. We think it's you, 9 Jeff. 10 MR. SCHWARTZ: Okay. So, first of all, thank 11 you very much for inviting me to share my thoughts 12 today. I think, Bob -- Mr. Bochner -- 13 (Outside noise.) 14 I think I'll wait. 15 (Pause.) 16 Okay. So thanks a lot for having me. I'm 17 very excited to share my thoughts with you all. I've 18 been following the committee closely from afar. I 19 watched the webcast of the last meeting, so it's a 20 little surreal. I actually recognize all of you, but 21 you don't recognize me. And that's all a little 22 surreal. 23 Anyway, so in preparing my comments for today, 24 what I tried to do is to make them as relevant as 25 possible for the Committee at this point in time as you 0186 1 all seek to improve market conditions for small and 2 emerging companies. 3 To that end, what I thought I would do was 4 first briefly assess the helpfulness of scaled disclosure 5 and other current efforts to provide regulatory relief 6 to small and emerging companies. I plan to focus on the 7 smaller reporting company or SRC rules that were adopted 8 a few years ago, and then talk a little bit about the 9 JOBS Act, which, of course, was adopted earlier this 10 year. 11 Second, I'll offer my thoughts on what might 12 be advisable next steps to build upon those recent 13 reform efforts. I'll offer suggestions about how to 14 identify candidates for reform, and I'll give a few 15 suggestions of my own. 16 And then finally, I'll discuss if -- rather 17 than having small and emerging companies trade alongside 18 large established ones in the same market as we do 19 today, it might be better for these firms to have their 20 own market, with each of these markets set up with 21 specifically designed regulatory frameworks. I think 22 that builds a lot on what Mr. Bochner was saying 23 earlier. 24 So, first, turning to the Smaller Reporting 25 Company rules, the SRC rules essentially provide for 0187 1 scaled disclosure for companies with a public float of 2 under $75 million. As was already brought up, what this 3 allows for, is it allows these companies to provide 4 fewer years of financial statements and less information 5 about their businesses and about their finances. 6 And while this seems like a nice change, 7 what's important to note about the SRC rules is that, in 8 substance, they're based upon around and largely a 9 continuation of the Small Business Issuer rules, which 10 has -- which had existed since 1992 throughout the 11 period of IPO decline. 12 What happened was that when the SRC rules were 13 put in place, the SEC essentially merged Regulation S-B 14 into Regulation S-K. And while this certainly cleaned 15 up the statute a lot, the adoption of these new rules 16 didn't do anything to offer any additional regulatory 17 relief to these small and emerging companies. 18 What the new rules did do, however, was 19 broaden access to scaled disclosure. Under Regulation 20 S-B, in order to qualify as a small business and to 21 receive scaled disclosures, you had to have under $25 22 million in revenues and a public float of under $25 23 million. Whereas, as I already alluded to, in order to 24 qualify for special treatment as an SRC, you can have up 25 to three times that amount in public float. 0188 1 So the rules did make a substantive change 2 here, in that, while they didn't actually provide for 3 more regulatory relief, at least they brought in the 4 number of firms that would be able to take advantage of 5 it. 6 But, as was already pointed out, $75 million 7 is a very small number. So it only extends the 8 regulatory relief to the smallest of the public 9 companies. 10 And while it's difficult to make too much of 11 this, the adoption of the SRC rules didn't seem to move 12 the needle much in terms of IPOs. In other words, the 13 IPOs continued to decline after the SRC rules were put 14 in place, which at least suggests that it didn't do much 15 to make the public market that much more attractive to 16 emerging companies. 17 So my bottom line for the SRC rules is that, 18 while their heart is in the right place with scaled 19 disclosure, the regulatory relief that the rules provide 20 was likely too modest to do much good for any companies 21 that we're concerned about. 22 The JOBS Act, though, can be seen as an 23 attempt to offer further assistance. And in contrast to 24 the SRC rules, the JOBS Act did make a lot of changes. 25 But I'm not that optimistic that the JOBS Act will do 0189 1 that much to improve matters either. 2 So one thing that the JOBS Act does is that it 3 focuses on emerging firms to the exclusion of small 4 ones. So small companies that went public prior to the 5 JOBS Act got no additional regulatory relief under the 6 statute. And similarly, those companies that do go 7 public under the JOBS Act lose the protection of the 8 statute after five years. 9 Another concern I have is that, even what the 10 JOBS Act does attract -- so what the JOBS Act does do is 11 it provides regulatory relief for emerging firms, I'm 12 afraid that the regulatory relief it provides for 13 emerging firms doesn't do enough to make the public 14 markets more attractive for them either. 15 What the JOBS Act does, among other things, is 16 that it eases the rules on providing research reports 17 regarding emerging companies, both before, during, and 18 after the IPO process, and it also adopts some scaled 19 disclosure. But the scaled disclosure that the JOBS Act 20 provides for is rather modest. 21 And with respect to the provision of research 22 reports, there's been some rumblings that investment 23 banks and analysts are taking a wait-and-see approach 24 before taking advantage of the regulatory flexibility 25 that the statute provides for. So I'm not confident 0190 1 that those JOBS Act reforms will lead to that many more 2 public companies. 3 And finally, one particular worry I have about 4 the JOBS Act is how the on-ramp provisions of the Act, 5 which are designed to make going public more attractive, 6 interact with the changes to Section 12(g), which, by 7 raising the shareholder thresholds which trigger public 8 reporting, makes it easier for companies to remain 9 private. 10 What I'm concerned about is that because of 11 the changes to Section 12(g), more companies are going 12 to opt to remain private, and that this undermines the 13 goal of the on-ramp provisions and also can contribute 14 to the further erosion of our public equity market. 15 While this might be defensible, while having 16 firms stay private might be a defensible outcome, it 17 might be a defensible outcome if we thought that the 18 private markets had something to offer these small and 19 emerging companies. If we thought the private markets 20 offered a viable alternative to small and emerging 21 firms, we might not be bothered by the fact that more 22 companies are opting to stay private. 23 But my own view is that the private markets 24 don't offer a viable alternative and that the lack of 25 regulatory structure that supports liquidity and 0191 1 investor protection, and I think they raise various 2 concerns to the extent that participation is limited to 3 QIBS and accredited investors to the exclusion of 4 everyone else. 5 The way I view the equity markets overall is 6 that there is a -- is that there is in fact -- no, let 7 me say it again. 8 The way I view the equity markets overall is 9 that even though we have scaling in the SRC rules and 10 through the JOBS Act, that even though we have this, 11 there is this vast gulf between the highly regulated 12 public stock markets and the lightly regulated private 13 markets, and that neither of these alternatives is 14 attractive to emerging companies. So it very much 15 builds on what Mr. Bochner was saying. 16 And I think in light of this vast gulf, 17 perhaps what is missing is an intermediate regulatory 18 framework. And the way I picture this framework is as 19 having many of the hallmarks of the public securities 20 regulation, but at the same time containing 21 significant-enough cuts to regulation to have a material 22 impact on the amount that the firms we're concerned 23 about actually spend on compliance. 24 Now, I'm under no illusion that regulatory 25 change would be a silver bullet. As the Committee has 0192 1 discussed, there are a number of reasons that explain 2 the decline in a small company market over time. But I 3 don't think that's a reason not to make regulatory 4 changes. I think that if we put our efforts into 5 designing an efficient regulatory structure, it would 6 help matters. 7 One way to go about this, one way to create 8 this improved intermediate regulatory structure would be 9 to broaden and deepen the scaling of regulations that 10 already exist under the current rules. 11 So first, looking at the broadening as already 12 noted, the SRC rules, special treatment under the SRC 13 rules is limited to companies under $75 million in 14 public equity outstanding. But there are far more 15 companies out there that could likely benefit from 16 regulatory relief. 17 In fact, maybe we should be looking at this 18 from a different perspective. Maybe instead of only 19 providing regulatory relief to the smallest public 20 companies, perhaps everyone should get regulatory 21 relief. Everyone, that is, except for the largest 22 public firms. 23 Several academics have pointed out that the 24 regulations that have been added on in recent years have 25 had the largest public companies in mind. They've been 0193 1 targeted at their misdeeds. And there's really been an 2 effort to hold these firms accountable for their 3 actions. And that, really, small and emerging companies 4 have just been caught up in the net. 5 If we look at the world this way, you can 6 picture a structure, a regulatory structure where the 7 largest public companies, the corporate high -- the S&P 8 500 type firms that make up the large percentage of the 9 market capitalization, that these companies are subject 10 to the highest regulatory scrutiny, but that small, 11 midsized, and emerging firms are subject to an 12 intermediate level of security. 13 So only the highest, only the largest firms 14 would have this highest level of scrutiny. Everyone 15 else would be subject to a subset under those 16 requirements. 17 Okay. But what should those -- what should 18 that subset be? So it's easy to say we should have an 19 intermediate regulatory structure, but, of course, it's 20 very difficult to actually come up with one. 21 In theory, regulation should decrease a firm's 22 cost of capital, right, as investors feel less of a need 23 to discount a firm's shares to account for fraud and 24 incomplete information. This means that in cutting 25 regulation, we raise the risk of actually raising a 0194 1 firm's cost of capital. And if we raise a firm's cost 2 of capital by more than we lower its compliance cost, 3 then we've actually done damage to the very firms that 4 we're trying to help. 5 If we look at the world this way, then what it 6 turns out we have to do is that we have to focus our 7 efforts on finding those regulations that cost the most 8 in terms of compliance, yet deliver the least in terms 9 of benefits, deliver the least in terms of investor 10 protection. 11 While this also is hard to do in practice, 12 here's a list of some candidates at least to think 13 about, some candidates for further discussion, for 14 further investigation. 15 So up here, as you look at the regulation 16 category, we have the usual suspects, I guess, of 17 Sarbanes-Oxley and Dodd-Frank. Smaller reporting 18 companies already get relief from Section 404(b) of 19 Sarbanes-Oxley, but perhaps they could also get relief 20 from 404(a), if not more. 21 Under Dodd-Frank, smaller reporting companies have a 22 temporary exemption from the Say-on-Pay rules, but 23 perhaps they could be exempt from a lot more of that Act 24 as well. 25 The Committee can also look at the MD&A, the 0195 1 Executive Compensation section of the Exchange Act 2 reports of these companies. There's already some scaled 3 disclosure for smaller reporting companies when it comes 4 to those areas, but perhaps these could be extended upon 5 as well. 6 But I don't think the committee needs to stop 7 and just look at how to scale regulation. I think there 8 are other areas where reforms could help lower costs as 9 well. 10 So if we look at the middle category, we have 11 the litigation environment. Perhaps steps can be taken 12 to make the litigation environment a bit less costly as 13 well. 14 One area that the committee could look at is 15 Rule 10(b)(5), at least as it pertains to secondary 16 market transactions. So let me flesh that out a little 17 bit. 18 So Rule 10b-5 is a foundational provision, 19 but legal academics have actually long questioned the 20 usefulness of 10b-5 damage awards against companies 21 for fraud in connection with secondary market 22 transactions in which the company played no role. 24 In these secondary market transactions, in 25 this context, where the issuer was not involved with the 0196 1 transaction, these damage awards tend to lack a term 2 function because the officers and directors who were 3 involved with the fraud are rarely personally liable 4 because they will be indemnified or insured. And these 5 awards also lack a compensation value as well because 6 what ends up happening is that these damage awards are 7 both paid by and paid to diversified shareholders. So 8 in the aggregate, what ends up happening is shareholders 9 end up paying themselves, minus a sizeable chunk for 10 attorneys. 11 So in light of this -- in light of the 12 circularity of 10b-5 damage awards in this context, 13 some academics have recommended a cap on 10b-5 damage 14 awards. Perhaps if we can -- if all companies are in 15 this cap, it can be something that can be applied to 16 small and emerging firms. 17 I also have up there Section 11 liability. 18 Section 11 is a provision of the securities laws that 19 allows shareholders to sue based on material 20 misstatements in registration statements. But the 21 shareholders do not need to show causation or (inaudible). 22 This heightened standard -- or I should say 23 this lowered standard in order to recover, this does 24 serve an investor protection function; that is, it provides 25 more protection for investors when they can sue without 0197 1 having as many elements to show. 2 But there are some folks out there who also 3 think that the risk of Section 11 -- the risk of Section 4 11 liability is deterring companies from going public 5 and also leading to overly costly and perhaps 6 duplicative due diligence efforts in order for companies 7 who are -- the companies are taking in order to -- in 8 order to avoid being sued. 9 So in light of the expenses that arise with 10 Section 11, perhaps Congress could amend the section, so 11 that rather than providing that shareholders can sue 12 based upon it, perhaps it can only be the SEC. 13 Finally, the other category I have up there is 14 listing standards. Today, among other things, New York 15 Stock Exchange, NASDAQ rules require that all the 16 companies have a majority independent board. And while 17 this also may serve an investor protection function, 18 it's actually empirically and theoretically contested 19 exactly how much investor protection good independent 20 directors do. And it turns out that independent 21 directors are particularly costly for small and emerging 22 companies. 23 So perhaps some thought can be given to using 24 these rules for small and emerging firms and simply 25 having these companies report on the extent to which 0198 1 their directors are independent. And this is already 2 required that they report on this, and perhaps that rule 3 would just be in case, and be the sole rule, that relates 4 to director independence. 5 MR. WALSH: Can I ask a question? What do you 6 mean the more expensive independent director? 7 MR. SCHWARTZ: So there's a study -- so 8 independent directors are just expensive because you 9 have to pay them, right? And it just -- it eats up a 10 greater percentage of the revenue of smaller firms to 11 pay these independent directors. 12 So there's been interesting studies out there 13 that show how much per dollar of revenue smaller 14 companies are paying on independent directors after 15 Sarbanes-Oxley, after these listing standards were put 16 in place, and it's a very high percentage, much higher 17 than it is for larger companies. 18 Does that answer your question? 19 MR. WALSH: Mm-hmm. 20 MR. SCHWARTZ: Great. 21 Okay. So those are my candidates for reform. 22 I offer these as food for thought. But I also think it 23 would be greatly helpful for the Committee, as part of 24 its ongoing efforts, to dive deeper into the costs and 25 benefits of securities regulation as it pertains to the 0199 1 companies that we're concerned about. 2 To add rigor to the difficult exercise of 3 recommending exact reforms to the SEC and Congress, I 4 think it would be helpful to do a couple of additional 5 things. 6 So one of which would be for the Committee to 7 either review or commission a review of the recent 8 empirical scholarship as it pertains to the cost and 9 benefits of securities regulation in this area. And 10 beyond that, the Committee could even undertake or 11 commission someone else to undertake its own study, a 12 study where it directly looks at the cost and benefits 13 of regulation in this area. 14 On the cost side, there can be a survey of 15 listed firms, preferably firms that are emerging 16 companies or smaller ones, to get a sense of what they 17 view as the most expensive and intrusive provisions. But 18 the cost is only one side of the equation, and likely 19 the easier side to measure. 20 It would also be beneficial for the Committee 21 to survey those who had input on the benefit side of the 22 securities laws. So to that end, there could be a 23 survey of sophisticated investors. Ask sophisticated 24 investors what they look at when valuing securities. If 25 they don't think something is important when valuing 0200 1 securities, likely it doesn't have that big of an 2 investor protection benefit. Because if it has an investor 3 protection benefit, that should be reflected in the price. 4 And these are the people who drive the prices. 5 So like I said, I think what I mentioned are 6 good areas to start looking, but I think digging deeper 7 into the cost and benefits through your own study or by 8 reviewing the empirical scholarship that already exists 9 would also prove helpful. 10 Okay. Finally, to transition just a little 11 bit abruptly into my final point, today, as we see on 12 the right side of the slide, we have emerging growth 13 companies and smaller reporting companies trading 14 alongside larger firms in the broader public market. 15 Because of this, the special regulatory 16 treatment to which SRC and emerging growth companies are 17 entitled under the JOBS Act and under the SRC rules, 18 because these firms trade alongside larger companies in 19 the broader market, this special regulatory treatment is 20 embedded within and, to the untrained eye, hidden within 21 the broader public markets. 22 If we simply continued to broaden and deepen 23 the regulatory relief provided under the JOBS Act and 24 the SRC rules, what we would also do is continue with 25 this construct, this construct where you have firms of 0201 1 various shapes and sizes all trading together, but all 2 subject to their own specific regulations. 3 But I'm not sure this is the best approach. 4 Instead, maybe it's better to separate things out, to 5 have firms -- to have different types of firms trade on 6 different markets, and to have these markets set up so 7 that they have regulations and a market structure that 8 actually fits these firms. And that's what we see on 9 the left side of the slide. 10 In my article that was included in the 11 background materials, I argue that we should have 12 separate markets for firms at different stages of their 13 lifecycle. So we would have a market for emerging 14 companies and a market for midsize and smaller 15 companies. And these markets could be subject to an 16 intermediate regulatory structure. 17 We would also have a market for large 18 companies. And this market for large companies would be 19 subject to the highest level of regulatory scrutiny. 20 And I offer this suggestion because I think 21 there are several benefits to separating different firms 22 out into different markets that are narrowly tailored to 23 fit those firms. 24 One advantage is that if we were to separate 25 things out in this way, we would have regulatory 0202 1 consistency within each market. All of the firms in the 2 market would be regulated similarly. This would mean 3 that they would be easily comparable, which would 4 increase efficiency on the market. Also, if we 5 separated things out in this way, there would be less of 6 a potential for investor confusion. 7 So, for example, let's say that Congress or 8 the SEC did choose to put a cap on its 10b-5 damage 9 awards for smaller companies. If this happened and if 10 these companies continued to trade alongside larger ones 11 in the broader public market, retail investors might not 12 realize that these smaller companies have this 13 limitation on litigation recovery. If, however, we had 14 smaller and emerging firms trade on their own markets, 15 we could make this limitation much clearer. 16 Another benefit of separating firms out into 17 different markets is that you could structure the market 18 itself to fit the firms that trade their own. So as 19 this Committee has discussed at length, smaller 20 companies face concerns regarding liquidity, and the SEC 21 or Congress may want to tackle those concerns by 22 allowing firms to choose their tick size or allowing 23 them to pay for liquidity or through some other avenue. 24 If regulators want to take that approach, I 25 think it would be much cleaner and much easier to do, if 0203 1 these firms actually traded on their own markets. 2 If instead you apply these tick size rules or 3 other liquidity rules to these firms in this broader 4 public market, I think it might be confusing, and it 5 might just be difficult to do, and clearer if they were 6 all separated out. 7 Like, it would -- for example, it would be 8 much easier if the midsize and smaller company market 9 had one tick size, and the large company market had 10 another. Or a small company market, you had a regime 11 where you could pick your tick size, whereas the large 12 company market you did not, something along those lines. 13 Finally, the last benefit is that today when 14 firms go public, they do so amidst a great deal of 15 regulatory uncertainty. A firm goes public under one 16 regulatory regime, but in a few years, there's a good 17 chance that the regulations that they will be subject to 18 will be much more demanding and expensive. And this has 19 to cause entrepreneurs to think twice about going public 20 at all, and must be doubly frustrating for emerging and 21 small companies who tend to get swept up in these 22 regulations that were meant to combat the misdeeds of 23 others. 24 I think if we separated these firms out into 25 different markets, it would be much more -- it would be 0204 1 much less likely that smaller and emerging companies 2 would be swept up in these reforms that were meant for 3 other types of companies. It would be much easier for 4 regulators to target reforms at the appropriate firms 5 and at the appropriate markets if different types of 6 firms were separated out into markets meant for them. 7 And I think if regulations in the future were 8 more well targeted at the appropriate group, it would 9 be -- it would be both fair and more efficient. 10 So although I think moving to a model where 11 you have different markets subject to different 12 regulations is different than the current scaling 13 approach that we've taken under the JOBS Act and the SRC 14 rules, I think it does offer some benefits and is, 15 therefore, a concept at least that's worth considering. 16 Thank you. I hope this helped. 17 MR. GRAHAM: I'm -- personally, I'm attracted 18 to that concept. I think the whole notion of having at 19 least two markets, or, you know, seeing some sort of 20 system so that you can be more targeted with respect to 21 the approach that you're taking with respect to each of 22 those markets, based on who's participating. 23 Have you given much thought to the feasibility 24 of actually implementing such a system? 25 MR. SCHWARTZ: A page worth in my article, out 0205 1 of 80. So I've thought about it. I have thought about 2 it a little bit, and I don't think it would be terribly 3 difficult. 4 So you already have the stock exchange. The 5 exchange is somewhat set up to have different markets. 6 So NASDAQ, for instance, has its BX Venture Market. You 7 could envision setting -- so today the BX Venture Market 8 has rules that are a little bit lesser than, but very 9 similar to the rules that govern the New York Stock 10 Exchange, more generally. You could picture that NASDAQ 11 venture market being governed by a different regulatory 12 template that is more intermediate in nature than it is 13 today, where it's just a slight tick below the New York 14 Stock Exchange. 15 So you could picture -- you could picture 16 markets adjusting -- you could picture the SEC working 17 with FINRA and the stock markets to actually change 18 regulations to fit existing -- to fit at least what 19 NASDAQ started to do. 20 So I don't think implementation would be easy, 21 but I don't think it's impossible either. It's just a 22 matter of changing listing standards and changing 23 regulations and having FINRA and the SEC and Congress 24 work together to do that. 25 (Talking simultaneously.) 0206 1 MR. GRAHAM: Go ahead. 2 MR. DENNIS: Oh, I was going to say, one, 3 we've got a market study for this. And kind of with 4 what Steven and I addressed on the previous Committee we 5 had, the big issue you've got to deal with is 6 perceptions because investors and companies are probably 7 going to view the emerging company market in your 8 example here as substandard compared to the large 9 company market. And so you, you know, you have to get 10 back by that psychological disadvantage. To me, the 11 regulations part, that's the easy part. 12 MR. GRAHAM: I don't think you have to do 13 that, though, because it says -- going back to the gap 14 that Steve was describing, you got your private 15 companies with a different set of rules, you got your 16 public companies with a different set of rules. There's 17 no particular stigma necessarily attached to being a 18 private company versus a public company. 19 But you do have this gap that is drawn between 20 those two segments. And if you just fill the gaps so 21 you have a natural progression, now I'm thinking 22 necessarily, you know, arrive at a situation where there 23 is going to be stigma attached to being in -- kind of 24 the first market that you hit to -- that you hit as your 25 company is evolving. 0207 1 You know, simply put, you have private 2 companies, then you have a market that is only for 3 accredited investors. Then as companies grow, you got 4 basically what we have now. 5 So it seems -- seems more like there's a way 6 of doing it without kind of stigmatizing the 7 participants the way, you know, Regulation S-B stigmatized 8 companies. 9 MR. DENNIS: I think -- I think that's the 10 biggest issue, is how do you -- I think like putting the 11 regulations together and how you logistically transition 12 is -- we can do that. I think the question is, will 13 people want to automatic -- the Facebooks of the world 14 are going to automatically want to jump to the highest 15 one and -- 16 MR. GRAHAM: That's good. They're -- you're 17 up to, you know, the Facebook stage, they have plenty of 18 resources in terms of compliance, etc. So, you know -- 19 so imposing on companies of that magnitude the 20 requirement that they go through the effort to provide 21 the level of extra protection that -- with registration 22 statement-type protection is not going to -- it's not 23 going to be an issue for them because, again, they will 24 have the resources. So -- 25 MR. BOCHNER: I guess the -- kind of 0208 1 reconciling what Professor Schwartz talked about and 2 what I talked about. I think the big difference, we 3 kind of came at the same problem at a slightly different 4 angle. 5 I think what I was envisioning was addressing 6 that market, that -- those reduced requirements, and 7 justifying that from an investor protection standpoint 8 by limiting access to investors that are deemed not to 9 need that greater protection. 10 And I think Professor Schwartz was sort of on 11 that same theme, but saying, well, let's -- let's do 12 that gradation by sort of size of company. And, you 13 know, then the question is -- you know, they're both 14 sort of the same ideas coming at it from a slightly 15 different angle. 16 But the concern I had was whether -- I think 17 yours is a bigger idea. I worry that it's more wood to 18 chop in the sense that you're exposing the -- you know, 19 you're exposing the non-accredited retail investor. I 20 guess it's a question, really. 21 As you envision sort of that lowest end 22 market, would you limit access to that market kind of 23 the way I've envisioned in my -- in my world, or would 24 you let any investor access all those markets, and they 25 just sort of buyer beware based on the gradations of 0209 1 listing standards and compliance? 2 MR. SCHWARTZ: I've thought about that a lot, 3 and I don't have any good evidence to support this view. 4 But my bias tends to be in favor of letting everyone 5 participate. I don't -- it bothers me to have markets 6 that are restricted to -- that have special access 7 privileges. I worry that retail investors aren't going 8 to have access to the best companies if that happens. I 9 maybe have this kind of bucolic attachment to public 10 markets where everyone can participate. 11 So I am in favor of letting everyone 12 participate and putting warning stickers on the market 13 so that people can choose whether they want to be 14 exposed to those risks. 15 And the other, I guess, more practical concern 16 I have with limiting access to this intermediate type of 17 regulatory structure would be I worry about liquidity 18 and that whether there would be enough interest among 19 accredited investors and institutional investors to 20 support that market. And if we have retail investors, I 21 think there is a better chance that we would have 22 liquidity. So I think there's a trade-off between 23 liquidity and investor protection, and I guess I kind of 24 err on the side of liquidity. 25 MR. BORER: Isn't there sort of an analogous 0210 1 situation right now with the OTC market where they have 2 this -- Cromwell Coulson runs this exchange. It used to 3 be the Pinks; they changed the name because I guess it's 4 a derogatory name -- where companies can list without 5 being fully reporting, whether it's a foreign company 6 that lists here without becoming SEC filers. 7 And they have, I think, three different tiers. 8 One at the bottom, which is somebody can trade a stock 9 with no reporting at all, there's no voluntary 10 disclosure through OTC market, and there's skull and 11 crossbones next to the name, all the way up to the ones 12 who may trade there and be fully reporting, SEC 13 compliant, etc. There's an intermediate level of 14 disclosure, whether it is voluntary reporting to OTC 15 markets, it's not a full SEC report. 16 And I don't know if anybody in the panel 17 looked at that study and said, this is an effective 18 market and it's a -- because I know with respect to a 19 lot of what I've done over the last couple years, 20 especially with foreign companies, they would come here 21 and say, we want to dip our toe in the water, whether 22 it's from German exchanges, Australian exchanges, a lot 23 of Canadian companies in the resource sector, etc., that 24 didn't want to go, say, fully to the SEC under MJDS and 25 register in the United States; we're taking this as a 0211 1 step. 2 And it seems to me, at least with respect to 3 the amount of trading that takes place there, that 4 there's got to be enough trading to provide some level 5 of good information to be able to decide whether it 6 works. 7 MR. SCHWARTZ: You're right. That's a great 8 point. The OTC market has tried to -- has tried to do 9 this. And I haven't looked at it extensively, but from 10 what I have looked at, they have not been that 11 successful. 12 So what would come close is the highest level 13 of the OTC market. I think it's OTCQX. That would be 14 kind of the most similar to what I would be proposing. 15 I think the difference would be -- and it goes 16 back to the point you raised on stigma. I think the OTC 17 really has a stigma attached to it, and I think that 18 prevents it from becoming this really true legitimate 19 alternative because it has a stigma, so companies 20 aren't -- aren't -- don't want to go there. I think OTC 21 has this reputation as being the place where companies 22 that are struggling can't meet the listing standards, 23 are going bankrupt, it has a stigma of being that 24 marketplace. So I think they haven't been able to 25 overcome that stigma, and I think that's one trouble 0212 1 they're having. 2 Another difference is that the regulations at 3 this OTCQX wouldn't be as high as I'm envisioning. At 4 OTCQX, you don't have to file Exchange Act reports. You 5 can do the OTC version of those reports. So it wouldn't 6 be -- it wouldn't be quite as high as what I would -- 7 what I had in mind. 8 And finally, unrelated to that, the difference 9 that I see is that the OTC market doesn't have -- 10 there's no SEC there telling them what their rules have 11 to be. So they're purely self-policed. The OTC markets 12 group polices the OTC because the securities laws don't 13 put any parameters -- don't put any parameters on what 14 their rules should be. Whereas from the market that I 15 envision, there would actually be this securities law 16 framework in place. 17 And I think that lends the market this 18 additional credibility, because when you just have a 19 market that's self-policed, I don't think it's a 20 credible market, and I think maybe that's also part of 21 the reason why it's not. It's not a substitute for what 22 I'm thinking about. 23 MR. GRAHAM: I want to just end things. Let's 24 pause the discussion so that Professor Bartlett can have 25 an opportunity to present. 0213 1 MR. BARTLETT: Sure. I can speak to some of 2 these issues about the market. 3 So first, I just want to thank you for 4 allowing me to share some of my thoughts on scaled 5 disclosure with you. 6 I also want to thank each of you for being on 7 this committee. I know you all have real jobs that 8 require an extraordinary amount of time. So the fact 9 that you decided to commit to this effort I think is 10 incredibly meaningful. It's very important work. 11 When Gerry first asked me to be on this panel, 12 it was something that I know is important because when I 13 practiced, I remember drafting 10-Ks and 10-Qs. And now 14 that I teach, I sort of sit back and I sort of observe 15 more generally sort of the evolution of these forms, and 16 it's clear there's this one-way ratchet that happens 17 with disclosure. Most of the time we're adding more 18 disclosure provisions, you know. So now we have 19 executive compensation disclosures, now we've got sort 20 of conflict mineral disclosures. It just keeps adding 21 on. You see risk factors too, right. I 22 suspect there's probably Y2K risk factors out there 23 somewhere still. 24 So it's great we have an effort that tries to, 25 you know, take a step back and rationalize whether or 0214 1 not we can actually have scaled disclosure that makes 2 sense. Because I certainly believe that's the case. At 3 the same time, I've also been daunted by the idea, and I 4 also tip my hat to you for taking on this task because 5 it's extraordinarily difficult to come up with optimal 6 disclosure. 7 I'm very pleased that Jeff and Steve are both 8 sort of more daring than I in actually coming up with 9 proposals. And I think they make a lot of sense. In 10 fact, I love this idea of sort of linking between SEC 11 disclosure documents and I’m thinking we can actually 12 plan to market something called a hyperlink. So 13 I think that would actually be a great addition of the 14 concept of EDGAR, basically come up with a way to use 15 technology in a way that makes it easier, doesn't kill 16 so many trees. 17 Okay. Well, what I'm going to talk about 18 today, though, notwithstanding this statement that I 19 actually want to see some unratcheting, some sort of 20 ratchet backwards, I'm going to talk about the 21 regulatory gap that I think you should fill. Okay. So, 22 in fact, Steve got wind of this and intended to leave, 23 but -- I'm just kidding, of course. 24 What I mean by this, well, what I want to talk 25 about is a regulatory gap that I think should concern 0215 1 us, if we're concerned about small and emerging 2 companies. Because the alternative of filling this gap 3 from the federal perspective is to allow the states to do 4 it, and we just don't want to have that. It's going to 5 increase the cost of capital, it's going to increase 6 complexity. I think it's something to be concerned 7 about. 8 So what I would like to begin with is just 9 sort of the conventional view of mandatory disclosure. 10 Generally, we sort of view the need for mandatory 11 disclosure as being driven by ownership structure. So 12 you might have privately held companies, family-held, on 13 one end of the spectrum, and at the other end of the 14 spectrum you've got dispersed shareholders, many 15 publicly dispersed shareholders, retail shareholders 16 that trade in the marketplace. 17 Now, we say that this is basically going to 18 map onto a disclosure regime, because if you're on the 19 far side, if you're a private firm, there's every reason 20 to believe you don't need mandatory disclosure because 21 your investors won't invest without contractually 22 getting rights to information. So this is a venture 23 capital model, for instance, right. That we don't have 24 mandatory disclosure there because we have sophisticated 25 investors that have a relationship and influence and 0216 1 they can get the information that they need. 2 That's different, however, if you have retail, 3 widely dispersed shareholders. You have large 4 information asymmetries between the shareholders and the 5 managers of those firms. There's also less of an 6 incentive to provide the information if you're not in a 7 capital-raising mode. And of course there's a 8 collective action problem because the investors may not 9 have, you know, the incentive necessary to demand the 10 information in the same fashion that a venture 11 capitalist would. So that's how we map our mandatory 12 disclosures by looking to the ownership structure. And 13 you see this in Section 12. 14 Section 12(a) basically says if you want to 15 trade on a stock exchange, you've got to be subject to 16 the Section 13 filing obligations, or if you have 17 greater than a certain number of record shareholders. 18 And sort of we'll table for the moment what that means 19 for a record shareholder. 20 So you have a certain number of shareholders 21 in ten million in assets, you also need to be subjected 22 to mandatory disclosure because we use that as a proxy 23 to say you're kind of in the public ownership space. 24 Okay. So therefore we're going to subject you to 25 mandatory disclosures. 0217 1 Now, to give you some examples, we have, you 2 know, plenty of private firms that don't disclose, or at 3 least privately owned. So Bechtel, for instance, 4 family-owned firm. Twitter, we say, you know, it's 5 generally a private company, for the most part, venture 6 capital investors and employee shareholders. On the 7 other end of the spectrum, you've got companies like 8 Google, GM. Zoom, it's a small -- it's a smaller public 9 company that trades on NASDAQ. And then we map that to 10 disclosure, which also is in some sense, it's all 11 spectrum, sort of, right? 12 So we have large accelerated filers that are 13 subject to all the rules. Then we also have smaller 14 reporting companies, which Jeff discussed, and Jennifer 15 provided a wonderful summary of a few meetings back, I 16 believe. 17 And so what we do is we then map these public 18 companies into their appropriate bucket, based on 19 whether they need the metric for smaller reporting 20 company status or otherwise the residual categories of 21 accelerated and non-accelerated filers. 22 These other firms, however, are not subjected 23 to Section 13. Okay. So the question to ask is: Should 24 we care about scaled federal disclosure in this? The 25 answer is yes. The reason I say yes is because if we 0218 1 don't regulate this from a federal matter, I believe, my 2 intuition and sort of my prediction is that we're going 3 to see increasing movement on the state front. So I 4 think that behooves us to think seriously about whether 5 or not it makes sense from both the issuer perspective 6 as well as an investor perspective to impose some form 7 of scaled disclosure in this space. 8 And one of the reasons I think this is going 9 to become more important, because that space has gotten 10 much, much bigger in light of the JOBS Act, because of 11 the fact now we went from 500 shareholders triggering 12 the thresholds all the way up to 2,000 non-employee 13 shareholders. 14 Okay. So that's basically why I think we 15 should care about this. 16 Just give you a quick outline of what I'm 17 going to talk about. I want to just go through in some 18 fashion the legal rules about why it is that these 19 private firms, these non-Exchange Act firms are in fact 20 subject to disclosure obligations. 21 I realize it sort of seems like a paradox or 22 just contradictory. So I'm going to explain why it's 23 not. I'm going to explain why there's some problems 24 with the state of affairs. And then lastly, I'm going 25 to explain what the Commission can do about it with its 0219 1 existing rulemaking authority. Okay. 2 So first, why is it that existing non-Exchange 3 Act companies are subject to disclosure obligations? 4 Well, let's take that -- take our dichotomy again. 5 Ownership on a scale, we also have a disclosure 6 vector as well. Let's not make it mutually exclusive. 7 So you have this two-by-two grid, right. You could have 8 on the one hand a privately owned company that 9 doesn't -- isn't subject to the federal regime. 10 So, for instance, Bechtel, okay, privately 11 owned. It doesn't -- it does not disclose anything 12 through the federal EDGAR system for instance. 13 On the other hand, you could have a public, 14 public company. You have GM, lots of dispersed 15 shareholders, and they also trade in the New York Stock 16 Exchange; and so, therefore, they're subject to Section 17 13. 18 But it turns out that these other two boxes 19 can also be filled. So to give you an example, Toys 'R 20 Us, privately held, went through a leveraged buyout a few 21 years ago. If you look them up on EDGAR, they're there. 22 Why did they do that? Anyone have a guess? 23 MR. WALSH: Debt. 24 MR. BARTLETT: What's that? 25 MR. WALSH: The debt. 0220 1 MR. BARTLETT: The debt, right. Because, of 2 course, the capital structure here is privately owned in 3 terms of the ownership, but it has widely dispersed 4 bondholders that was funded the LBO through high yield debt. 5 And so, therefore, the bond investors, through the power 6 of covenant, they say thou shalt file all Section 13 Act 7 reports because that helps facilitate the trading market 8 for high yield debt. 9 We also have this other category here. So 10 these are companies that are privately held. I'm sorry. 11 They're private in terms of their disclosure. They do 12 not show up on EDGAR, in terms of their Section 13 13 report. 14 But if you look at their ownership structure, 15 they're kind of public. In fact, on this spectrum of 16 ownership, they have drifted far from the family-owned 17 model, much toward the Google widely dispersed 18 shareholder model. So Twitter, for instance, got that 19 way because of SecondMarket and SharesPost, and the ability 20 to basically trade off the grid through private resale 21 transactions. 22 And likewise, Proxim Wireless trades on the 23 over-the-counter market it was formerly the Pink Sheets, 24 and rebranded itself on the OTC market. And I'd like 25 you to just take a look at Proxim, for instance, and why 0221 1 it is the case that I'm making a claim that this is a 2 public company that raises all the same problems that we 3 have with information asymmetry and the inability to 4 contractually get information that investors might want. 5 So if you go to OTC Market. Okay. Here we 6 go. And we added the Proxim symbol. So far this kinda 7 looks and feels like NASDAQ. You get Proxim Wireless 8 Corporation. You see the inside quote. You see the 9 price, $1.55. You see the volume. Doesn't trade a lot, 10 but it does trade. You also get a lot of other metrics. 11 For instance, there is some financial information, but 12 it hasn't been -- they haven't filed any information 13 since 2010. Okay. This is a formerly public company, 14 public Exchange Act that went dark. They now trade OTC. 15 And they do in fact trade. So here, for 16 instance, historical trades of Proxim. You see it's not 17 a lot of volume, but in any given day you could have a 18 few thousand shares change hands. And these, of course, 19 are changing hands among dispersed shareholders. This 20 company, from an ownership perspective, is actually 21 quite far along the spectrum from private to public. 22 So my contention is that it's a publicly 23 traded firm and so it raises the same policy 24 considerations that have long justified mandatory 25 disclosure. 0222 1 Now, why isn't it subject to federal mandatory 2 disclosure? Well, that's just a function of the way 3 that the federal securities laws work. If you're a 4 securities lawyer, this will make a lot of sense to you; 5 if you're not, just trust me. 6 So basically -- so the way it works -- so if 7 you want to avoid Section 13 obligations, then you make 8 sure that you don't trade on the stock exchange, and 9 that you have fewer than the requisite number of record 10 holders. 11 And it turns out, by the way, that record 12 holders is actually just based on a formal requirement 13 of who is showing up as a stockholder record on your 14 books. Most shares are held in indirect form, so it 15 turns out that those number of record holders bears 16 almost no relationship to the number of beneficial 17 owners. 18 So the number of record holders of General 19 Motors, for instance, is a staggering 275. Okay. So if 20 it turns out that if General Motors decided to delist 21 from the New York Stock Exchange, it could go dark 22 tomorrow, okay, because it has fewer than 300 record 23 holders, which is all that's required in order to file a 24 Form 15 and go dark. 25 Okay. So in any event, though, this is the 0223 1 method that you do it, is that you would get off the 2 Exchange, and you have fewer than the triggering number 3 of shareholders. 4 Now, you can't raise any money because if you 5 want to raise any money, you're probably going to be 6 subjecting yourself to Section 5 of the '33 Act, which 7 requires registration. Okay. 8 But if you're not raising capital, as many 9 firms aren't, you can delist and you can stay underneath 10 this 300 shareholder record and you can be fine. 11 Now, your selling shareholders are also 12 subject to registration requirements, which could force 13 them to come up with a disclosure document. But it 14 turns out that the selling shareholders, reselling 15 shareholders and the dealers that work with them are 16 going to be exempt under some exemption to Section 5, 17 which is known as Section 4(1), 4(3) exemptions. So you can do it. 18 But that doesn't mean that you're not without 19 disclosure obligations. Why? Well, because you get one 20 great thing by being subject to all of these -- sort of 21 this onerous Section 13 reports. In exchange for 22 subjecting yourself to the conflict minerals disclosure, 23 you get federal preemption of state law. Okay. And 24 that comes about through something called Section 18 of 25 the '33 Act which says that if you are trading a covered 0224 1 security, then the state, they can regulate fraud, but 2 they can't regulate the disclosure documents that 3 pertain to you. And that's really important to 4 understand, because it turns out that each state has its 5 own separate securities regime. They're called Blue Sky 6 laws. They work just like the federal regime. They 7 basically enforce disclosure obligations and they police 8 fraud. 9 Okay. So if you are a company, you have 10 shareholders across the states, as many companies that 11 raise capital in our marketplace do, you have to worry 12 about complying with potentially 50 different state 13 regulations. This is a huge mess. It's been a long 14 mess ever since Blue Sky laws sort of were developed in 15 the early 20th Century. It became a special mess when 16 we then had a federal regime in the 1930s. 17 So you had a dual regime where you had to 18 comply with the federal regime and the 50 different 19 states. It was such a mess, in fact, that Congress 20 said, let's clean it up and create one standard, the 21 federal standard. This would happen in 1996 through 22 something called the National Securities Market 23 Improvement Act and basically created Section 18. Okay. 24 So as long as you're trading a covered security, you only 25 have to comply with one disclosure boss, and that's the 0225 1 federal government. 2 And the way that it works, it says if your 3 securities are listed on a major stock exchange, it's a 4 covered security. 5 Alternatively, if the securities are sold in a 6 Section 4(1) or 4(3) resale transaction and you're subject to 7 13, then you're also going to preempt the state law. 8 Okay. 9 Now, what happened is that when you have OTC 10 transactions occurring, those companies that are not 11 subject to Section 13 filing obligations and they don't 12 trade in an Exchange, they no longer have the power of 13 saying these are covered securities. 14 So as a result, these transactions are all 15 going to be subject to the litany of state securities 16 laws that regulate resale transactions. 17 And so, for instance, here in California we 18 have 25130, which basically says that it's illegal to 19 resell a transaction unless you file a disclosure 20 document. There's exemptions to it, but, as I read the 21 exemption, they are rarely met in a lot of resale 22 transactions that take place in these marketplaces. 23 So let's just take a look at these exemptions 24 that apply, right. So you're now off the grid. You're 25 at Proxim, right. How does Proxim make sure that 0226 1 they're not going to get in trouble with the various 2 state securities laws because these resale transactions are 3 taking place without being a covered securities? 4 Well, there's a handful of exemptions. These 5 exemptions are often mapped onto something called a 6 Uniform Securities Act. It didn't take long to figure 7 out the 50 conflicting securities laws, which are 8 complicated. So the national -- the state securities 9 commissioners did actually try to come up with a uniform 10 system of state securities laws. However, it's just a 11 template. So the states are free to tweak it around the 12 edges, and they have tweaked it considerably since it 13 came out in the 1950s. 14 But generally, the exemptions try to map onto 15 these three resale exemptions. And so one of them, for 16 instance, says that if you're not using a broker, if 17 it's like an eBay transaction, right, if I just decide 18 to sell a security to someone who is interested in the 19 market without using a broker, then 20 theoretically we won't worry so much about that because 21 it's brokers that we have to worry about, because, as we 22 have heard about this morning, they really get on the 23 phone and try to market a stock, okay, which might be a 24 concern for any number of reasons. So this unsolicited 25 resale transaction, it's going to be exempt. 0227 1 At the same time, we also have an exemption 2 that says if it's an isolated sort of one-off 3 transaction, even if it involves a broker, that can 4 be -- that can be okay as well, as long as you know -- 5 if it's basically you're just -- you know, house caught 6 fire, you sell your -- sort of your holdings of Proxim 7 securities, it's the only time you ever sold it, we 8 generally allow you a free pass as well. 9 Likewise, there's always private resale 10 transactions. It's a -- in California, for instance, it 11 says if you sell to an accredited investor effectively, 12 it's also going to be exempt. 13 And there's also something called a manual 14 exemption, which is incredibly important actually for 15 complying state laws. And what it says is that if you 16 aren't subject to Section 13 and if you want to have an 17 active market in your securities on the OTC, what you're 18 supposed to do is you're supposed to file your annual 19 financials with a recognized manual. And the manual is 20 published by a couple of agencies, which tend to be agencies 21 rating as well as Standard & Poor's. Mergent is 22 one as well. And these are all publicly available and 23 so you're supposed to be able to go and look up Proxim's 24 last balance sheet. 25 Turns out, however, that it's not perfect 0228 1 because this is only possible in 37 states. The 2 conditions for being manual eligible differ in these 37 3 states. And the manual doesn't exist in certain states 4 such as California, which tend to be a large market. So 5 that's -- that's -- that's one limitation. 6 And there's one other thing, too, that 7 imposes, while I'm staying with these private 8 non-Exchange Act companies are actually subject to 9 disclosure obligations, is because there's actually a 10 federal rule that applies to a broker-dealer. And it's 11 Rule 15c2-11. 12 It says that if you want to quote a security 13 that's not on NASDAQ, it's not an exchange, then you 14 have to make sure that you get -- you receive from the 15 company some financial information. It's about 16 items 16 of information. It basically says that you can't 17 legally trade as a broker-dealer quote unless you get 18 these 16 items of information. So they include things 19 from basic corporate details, who the officers and 20 directors are, and some financial information, so 21 balance sheet and a recent income statement. So those 22 are some of the disclosure obligations that apply. 23 So that's why I contend that these 24 non-Exchange Act firms are in fact subject to disclosure 25 obligations. 0229 1 Now, what are the problems with it? Well, 2 first of all, let's take a look at the state resale 3 exemptions, why you might even be uncomfortable if 4 you're a company on OTC being subjected to these 5 requirements. 6 So the first one is that it's just complex. 7 Okay. So if you represent Proxim and you -- I mean, I 8 would sort of go running and screaming if I was aware 9 that, you know, the company wants to have investors or 10 raise capital across 50 different states potentially. 11 I feel fortunate that most of my clients were 12 in fact having covered securities, so that I only have 13 to worry about one federal regime, which is complicated 14 enough. 15 So, for instance, you know, what is an 16 isolated transaction? It turns out that you're going to 17 have to look how states have interpreted that, and they 18 might differ in how they interpret it. 19 For instance, likewise, has the state complied 20 with the manual requirements, which might differ across 21 different states as well? 22 What about these non-manual states, like 23 California; have you complied with their somewhat 24 idiosyncratic resale requirements? So it's complex in 25 order to have a compliant resale regime in this domain 0230 1 or to raise capital across these 50 states. 2 There's also the question about whether or not 3 these resale transaction exemptions still make sense. 4 And the reason I think that this is something that we 5 might see some movement on recently is that the space 6 that we're talking about here, these publicly traded 7 private firms is growing by leaps and bounds. It's 8 growing very, very quickly. It's going to grow even 9 quicker because of the JOBS Act. 10 And so this is a period of time where we might 11 see these provisions being tested by state regulators 12 and say, you know what, this unsolicited quote 13 transaction, I don't know if it makes much sense because 14 all of a sudden these broker-dealers are saying they're 15 getting tons of unsolicited interest. Why? Well, 16 because OTC marketplace is online. It's very easy if 17 you're interested in sort of trading, just sort of 18 submit an order that's not solicited just by virtue of 19 the technology of the OTC market today. 20 So you can see that this might be nearing a 21 time when some of these exemptions might simply 22 disappear. And in fact that has been the case in some 23 of the states. 24 And so, for instance, the manual exemption has 25 been eliminated in certain states in recent years as 0231 1 well out of concern that it's really not a very 2 functional way to assure investor protection in a 3 publicly traded over-the-counter marketplace. 4 And then likewise, I think there's reason to 5 believe that because of the complexity, because of past 6 attendance of only focusing on the federal regime, a lot 7 of companies just aren't complying with these rules. And 8 why -- and here's a quote, by the way, from "The 9 Corporate Counsel" talking about SharesPost and 10 SecondMarket. These rules all apply to those firms as 11 well. And they say: "Companies on these markets often 12 ignore the Blue Sky stuff; they don't require that 13 counsel's opinions address these matters." 14 And when I talk with participants in this 15 market, I am curious what these legal opinions cover, 16 because typically you're going to get a resale legal 17 opinion, and they tend to govern the '33 Act and they 18 don't cover state securities law, although I would love 19 to hear whether that has changed over time. 20 The reason I think that this is problematic is 21 because a lot of these state provisions have the same 22 remedy for violations of the registration requirement 23 that the federal regime is, which is rescission. And so 24 it very well may be the case a lot of people are walking 25 around with effective put options on the stock that they 0232 1 purchased in the over-the-counter marketplace, which can 2 create a huge mess in the event that the company 3 underperforms. And I'm not sure that this option is 4 actually being priced in the marketplace, as of course 5 it should be. 6 Okay. So as I said, these are some of the 7 problems. I think these problems may be -- oh. With 8 the state disclosure, here are some problems with 9 15c2-11 disclosure. This is not news. This is one of 10 the more critiqued rules that I've seen by the SEC. 11 Basically some of the problems are it only 12 governs initiation of quotations. So of course the 13 financial information that the broker-dealer gets could 14 get stale very, very quickly. 15 It doesn't cover at all the situation on 16 SecondMarket or SharesPost, where there's no quotation 17 being done by a broker-dealer. Those tend to be more 18 like -- well, SharesPost claims it's a patented bulletin 19 board. These represent customer interests. There's no 20 quotes there being offered. So it doesn't apply at all 21 in those markets. 22 There's no public repository of this 23 information as well. So it goes in a file of the 24 broker-dealer. And they have to make it available upon 25 request, but there's no public repository like there is, 0233 1 for instance, say, with the SEC. 2 And then there's a bunch of exemptions that 3 broker-dealers have to the rule, which also limits its 4 effectiveness. 5 So, for instance, it doesn't apply to 6 unsolicited quotations. This is actually dual-pronged. 7 Pink Sheets actually got concerned that broker-dealers 8 were saying, we don't need to have the 15c2-11 9 information to quote because we're getting unsolicited 10 interest. Because of course they could realistically 11 say, we're getting a lot of trading interest because of 12 the electronic platform of OTC market. 13 And then likewise, there's something called 14 the piggyback exception, which basically says that as 15 long as you see the market maker quoting a security, and 16 that security has been quoted for 30 days with no more 17 than four lapses of quotations, you can go ahead and 18 start quoting that security as well without having to 19 get the 15c2-11, even if the original person who got 20 that information has decided to stop making a market. 21 And so you can have piggyback after piggyback after 22 piggyback without anyone knowing even where the 15c2-11 23 form actually is. 24 Okay. So not surprisingly, this is -- again, 25 as I said, it's been heavily critiqued. It's been 0234 1 critiqued -- and there was proposals actually to amend it in 2 the '90s that never survived. There was a roundtable 3 market structure, a microstructure last October, I 4 believe, where this came up as well as in need of 5 potential reform. 6 This is -- the CEO of Pink Sheets describes 7 "Rule 15c2-11 is a rule of darkness," as opposed to a 8 rule of transparency. 9 Okay. So there's some problems, and these 10 problems are going to become potentially more serious, I 11 think, to contend with for companies that trade in this 12 space, the space as well that both Steve and Jeff are 13 talking about potentially to invigorate in terms of the 14 marketplace. I think these legal problems are going to 15 grow. 16 So to give you a sense, there are 3,000 OTC no-17 information firms. Okay. I looked in June, and there's 18 about 2,700. 300 more somehow appeared in just the span 19 of a few months. Okay. This is a marketplace that is 20 growing by leaps and bounds. And for reasons that you 21 can probably all understand, because who wants to comply 22 with the conflict mineral rule if you have a marketplace 23 where you have real liquidity without the need to comply 24 with any of the disclosure obligations? 25 Also, the reason I think that states are 0235 1 getting increasingly focused on this space is because 2 they already are concerned. So in response to the JOBS 3 Act, for instance -- here's the President of the 4 National Association of Securities Enforcers. His 5 testimony says we have -- and this is in specific 6 response to increasing the 500 threshold to 2,000, or I 7 think it was 1,000 at the time. 8 He said, "We do have concerns about drastic 9 changes in the thresholds for reporting companies or the 10 information they must disclose. The primary reason for 11 requiring a company to be public is to facilitate 12 secondary trading of the company's securities by 13 providing easily-accessible information to potential 14 purchasers. The principal concerns for states is the 15 facilitation of this secondary trading market with 16 adequate and accurate information." 17 So it's already on the radar. Okay. So this 18 is why I think that it could potentially be an 19 increasingly important issue for companies in this 20 space. 21 As they say, you know, Eliot Spitzer has had 22 kind of an interesting career. I think it might be 23 interesting for me as well to see where I might be able 24 to find some exciting regulatory initiatives. 25 So, again, it's just a prediction. I'd be 0236 1 happy to be proven wrong, but it's something, I think, 2 to take seriously. 3 So what can the Commission do about it? I 4 don't think doing nothing makes sense. A wait-and-see 5 approach is going to I think potentially be problematic 6 for companies because they're going to have to choose 7 between do I want to comply with these 50 -- you know, 8 these 50 different states and all the complexity that 9 imposes, or do I file Section 13 reports, as unappealing 10 as that is? That's kind of a Hobson's choice. I'm not 11 sure we really want to put companies in that position. 12 So what I think makes sense is a uniform 13 system of disclosure. I think that that actually 14 facilitates capital formation for smaller companies, 15 again, because it simply makes it easier to see your 16 transaction cost, people understand it. It's good for 17 investors because if it -- if the disclosure regime 18 makes sense, it can help eliminate some of the 19 information asymmetries that we all know drive the need 20 for mandatory disclosure. 21 So I'm a fan of uniform, a uniform system of 22 law. So all the Federalists in the audience, I 23 apologize. 24 So there are two rulemaking approaches that you 25 can take if you're the SEC. And as a Committee, I would 0237 1 urge you to consider these. I think one is superior. 2 So one is you could focus on 15c2-11. It's 3 got lots of problems. It's -- you could eliminate the 4 piggyback exemption. That's been proposed already. I 5 can't take credit for it. 6 You could make the information more easily 7 accessible, have a public repository. That's also 8 already been suggested, so I can't take credit for that 9 as well. In fact, I would urge you to go back to the 10 original proposal of 1998, I believe, to reform this 11 rule, because these problems with it are well-known. 12 Why might that help? It would help in the 13 sense that at least the problem wouldn't look so 14 dramatic to state securities regulators, right. They 15 wouldn't be able to point to 15c2-11 and say, you know, 16 this rule of darkness requires us to step in and 17 regulate. 18 However, it's not preemption. It's not a very 19 strong form of creating a uniform system. And so what 20 can the Commission do? 21 Well, it turns out that the Commission still 22 has Section 18 to work with, and it actually has some 23 rulemaking authority within Section 18 that gives it -- 24 that creates the authority to reach into non-Section 13 25 Exchange Act companies and say, you need to start 0238 1 reporting on a scaled basis if you want to preempt state 2 laws. 3 Okay. So the way that this could work, for 4 instance, is two ways. One, the SEC was long ago 5 empowered to create a covered security if it was sold to 6 a qualified purchaser, as defined by the SEC. There was 7 a proposal once to say a qualified purchaser is is any 8 accredited investor. That never became a final rule, so 9 this has yet to be defined by the SEC. 10 So one approach you might consider, if you 11 worry about this, is to say that, well, look, what we'll 12 do is we'll give you preemption, Proxim, conditional on 13 your selling to a qualified purchaser defined as an 14 individual who either has access to information or you 15 provide specified disclosure. 16 This is actually not a new idea, in fact. 17 This is how we long -- have long interpreted the private 18 placement rule, which says that you can sell to 19 sophisticated investors, but sophistication being 20 defined as either someone who has access to information 21 or someone who has been provided with requisite 22 disclosure documents. 23 Okay. So you can simply say a qualified 24 purchaser, just like we use -- do in the 4(1) -- or the 25 4(2) jurisprudence. We say that if you sell to someone 0239 1 who has access like a venture capitalist or someone who 2 doesn't necessarily have access, like a retail investor, 3 but you give them a disclosure document that has an 4 appropriate amount of information, certainly not all 5 Section 13 information, but maybe something that's 6 scaled appropriately for an over-the-counter company, 7 then you can get federal preemption. 8 An alternative approach as well is to say that 9 covered security includes a security sold in a resale 10 transaction under Section 4(1) or 4(3), which is most 11 non-insider resale transactions, if the company files 12 Section 13 reports. 13 So one approach is to do what high yield 14 investors do, is they say, we know that you're not 15 required to file Section 13 reports, but you can always 16 voluntarily file Section 13 reports. And so one 17 approach is to simply use that model and say, what we'll 18 do is we'll create a special set of Section 13 reports 19 that are only eligible to be used if you create the 20 right classification of a company. 21 That might be one of these companies that Jeff 22 was suggesting, that sort of -- you know, a small tech 23 company that doesn't trade on the New York Stock 24 Exchange. Or another criteria that indicate that we're 25 really trying to focus on the eligibility. 0240 1 To use these forms, you have to be like 2 Proxim, a company that doesn't want to be subjected to 3 Section 13 but trades in a public marketplace. 4 So if you do that, they may then voluntarily 5 choose to file these sort of lighter forms of Section 13 6 and then claim that the resale transactions are exempt 7 because they're done under 4(1) and 4(3) and we are 8 voluntarily filing Section 13 reports; and so, 9 therefore, these are covered securities. 10 So those are two approaches I think that make 11 the most sense because you get federal preemption. And 12 I think this is sort of, at least in my mind, an issue 13 that is going to increasingly become a problem for small 14 and emerging companies that operate currently in this 15 unregulated space beneath, well, 2,000 shareholders as 16 of today. So that's all for that. 17 MR. GRAHAM: Thank you, Bobby. 18 Couple more minutes before we break at 3:00. 19 Any more questions for Jeff or Bobby? 20 (No audible response.) 21 Hearing none -- 22 MS. JACOBS: Yeah, why don't we take a quick 23 five-minute break, and then we're going to open up for 24 discussion. And, please, as many members as possible 25 hang around because this is where we're going to need 0241 1 y'all. 2 (A brief recess was taken.) 3 MR. GRAHAM: I'd like to get started with the 4 discussion, kind of our -- kind of our discussion part 5 of the afternoon. Surely, it's one of the more 6 important parts. I wish that we had more time for it, 7 but we don't. And I also understand that there are a 8 number of people that have planes to catch, and so - -I 9 think maybe before we actually conclude, so I want to 10 get started and give everybody an opportunity to weigh 11 in a little bit. 12 Again, so going back to what we said this 13 morning, the purpose of today was to look at two general 14 areas and think about what kind of recommendations we 15 can make with respect to those areas that would help 16 further the interests that we're trying to further as a 17 committee. 18 Those, of course, are the structural issues 19 that we find in the marketplace, number one, and, number 20 two, the scaled disclosure. 21 You know, I think what I would -- what I would 22 like to do is have a conversation. We heard -- we've 23 heard a lot things today. I think some were kind of 24 more interesting from kind of a broader -- kind of a 25 context point of view; I think others more directly 0242 1 related to what it is that we're trying to accomplish in 2 terms of coming up with specific recommendations. 3 So what I would like to do is begin the 4 conversation and, at least before we break, have a 5 sense for where we feel we should be headed as a 6 committee. 7 If one or two specific recommendations fall 8 out of the discussion, great. If not, that's okay too. 9 But let's begin the discussion. And then I think what 10 is likely to happen is that following this meeting we 11 will -- you know, Chris and I will think about what 12 we've heard and begin to kind of draw some 13 recommendations into focus that we've been discussing to 14 help finalize. 15 Before we kind of open it up for discussion, I 16 think Chris has a couple of things she would like to 17 say. 18 Is that true? 19 MS. JACOBS: Yeah. Just to begin to set the 20 stage for the discussion, we've spent several meetings 21 on the IPO Task Force, the IPO on-ramp. And as we begin 22 the discussion this afternoon, maybe ask y'all to change 23 momentum here a second and look towards day two. 24 The one thing I know, as a sitting CEO, is you 25 don't ever create or set up with your company with your 0243 1 IPO as your end game. Your IPO should be the beginning 2 of your next step. And that next step and what that 3 environment entails for us is what we need to discuss 4 today. Because the environment for these public 5 companies, day two. Once the IPO is finished, we have a 6 set of rules and regulations that are well documented as 7 being a burden. 8 Professor Schwartz, I'll probably be putting 9 you in my will sometime next week because you hit a lot 10 of the points that I think we -- I'd like to see us 11 cover. 12 And I would like to hear whether you're an 13 investor. And maybe as investors, y'all don't have a 14 dog in that hunt, but to those of us that are associated 15 with small reporting public companies, there's a lot of 16 reform that could be done now that's not quite the 17 burden of perhaps a new set of markets. Because we've 18 got that -- let me give you an example. 19 We've got the $75 million market cap as the 20 hurdle for exemption. Well, as you brought up, Professor 21 Schwartz, why is that 75 million, when the JOBS Act has 22 given a hurdle rate of a billion dollars in revenue 23 and five years of reprieve? There is a real disconnect 24 here. 25 And so all I wanted to do is sort of set the 0244 1 stage on what we were hoping we would hear from you this 2 afternoon about scaling and that day two for these 3 public companies. 4 MR. GRAHAM: One last maybe point of order, 5 how would you guys like to manage the discussion? I 6 would like to hear from everyone. 7 MR. SUNDLING: Free flowing. 8 MR. GRAHAM: Would you like to comment on both 9 scaling and the kind of market issue, or shall we spend 10 a half an hour on market issues and then switch over to 11 scaling? 12 MR. SUNDLING: I think it depends on who's 13 speaking. 14 MS. JACOBS: Yeah. 15 MR. SUNDLING: And -- yeah. If you don't -- I 16 don't know what everybody else thinks, but I think that 17 the opinions and the things that people might want to 18 talk about are going to differ depending on your 19 background, what company you're representing here. 20 MR. GRAHAM: Oh, absolutely. I don't disagree 21 with that. 22 So why don't we just kind of start with maybe 23 the structural issues, and some people have more to say 24 on that and others less, and then we'll move on to the 25 subject of scaling, if that's okay. 0245 1 So we've heard a lot about tick size, whether 2 that matters. I guess what I'd like to do is, again, 3 just kind of open things up for discussion, think about 4 what we might want to say about that as a committee. 5 Does anyone want to start? 6 MR. SUNDLING: I'll start, if you don't mind. 7 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. 8 MR. SUNDLING: But if you don't mind, I'd like 9 to back up just a little bit. 10 So first of all, the speakers and presenters 11 here today have been phenomenal. Thanks for your 12 participation. I know I learned a lot, probably a lot 13 of -- you know, there was a lot of information there 14 that I don't think I absorbed today, maybe never will. 15 Some extremely deep expertise from David on the way 16 the trading markets work and from the professor on kind 17 of the observation around -- you know, I saw a lot of 18 analysis done on just charts of what the markets are 19 doing. 20 But I think, you know, if we back into what's 21 the charter of this committee in looking at capital 22 formation is one problem, and a form of capital 23 formation is going public, right. So you go public to 24 raise money, and then, you know, as Christine said, then 25 what's your Phase II once you are public? 0246 1 And so coming from the angle of a sub $50 2 million software company, right, so everybody -- we got 3 investment bankers here, we got regulators, and folks 4 from the academic world -- from my perspective, if 5 you -- and I belong to a lot of groups, right, with a 6 bunch of other CEOs that are in the same -- probably in 7 100 million and below software space. You don't even 8 talk about IPOs anymore, right. 9 It's -- and I think we have to realize that, 10 for all intents and purposes -- you know, I keep 11 thinking about the regulatory changes they're talking 12 about. That's akin to kind of just bumping this can a 13 quarter inch at a time, and it needs to move five feet, 14 right, to really get people excited about the objective 15 of becoming a publicly traded company. 16 There's got to be radical reform, not just 17 around regulatory requirements. But I think there's a 18 marketing problem, right. I think that if you turn the 19 clock back to 1996, the only thing anybody ever talked 20 about was the IPO. 21 You talk to any of these CEOs, and we're -- 22 you know, we're trying to extrapolate from these market 23 statistics and all these other things what they might be 24 thinking. It's easy. Just survey them. Call them. I 25 talk to them all the time. And I am one of them, and we 0247 1 would never consider an IPO. 2 And with all due respect, right, if the idea 3 is to figure out -- you know, all the things that I even 4 heard in the last few hours and then in prior sessions 5 is you're not selling me on going public, that's for 6 sure, right. It's -- 7 MS. JACOBS: Why is that, Charlie? 8 MR. SUNDLING: Well, I think just -- it's 9 just -- it's difficult. And when you look at the exit 10 options, you always have to see what is the competition. 11 The competition for liquidity is M&A. The M&A market’s 12 red hot, right. It's not hassle-free. Nothing is. 13 But really compared to going public, it's an easy way 14 out. You've got investors. 15 You know, when Steve was here, I think it was 16 he who made the statements from a VC perspective, right, 17 there's kind of two things they look at. One is in the 18 initial discussions, who's your buyer, you know we're 19 going to put money in you, who are the most likely 20 buyers, which is a very fair question. 21 And from an IPO perspective, it's -- I think 22 he said a hundred million in revenue or bigger, and 23 market cap, you know, day one IPO, nearing the billion 24 dollar mark, before you get any, you know, of the A 25 player anyhow, i-bankers involved in your deal. 0248 1 But I think the perception that I have, and I 2 spend a lot of time, and I realize the complexity. We 3 do a lot of complex stuff in our business, right. Our 4 customers are very big global energy companies, nuclear 5 power producers. So everything we do is complicated. 6 I'm not afraid of complicated. When I look at 7 what it's going to take to go public and remain public 8 in all those -- you know, until you reach a very 9 substantial scale, it's not even the money, a million 10 bucks a year, whatever, to pay the auditors and all 11 that. It's more the risk. It's the distraction from 12 your business. It's the fact that, from a liquidity 13 standpoint, it's a lot easier to get a big check from a 14 strategic buyer, right. 15 And so I think in looking at -- so there's the 16 two things that we've maybe been -- the two big things 17 anyhow brought together to discuss is access to capital, 18 and then somewhere along the line this whole discussion 19 about IPOs came in because I think it related to access 20 to capital, as far as I can tell. 21 And then you get into the systemic functioning 22 of the market, right. So on the trading side, right, 23 the things that David brought up about, you know, the 24 spreads and on, you know, the decimalization and all 25 these things that are kind of impediments to that side 0249 1 of the market. 2 You combine that with kind of the -- you know, 3 this whole notion of what still sticks in the minds of 4 every entrepreneur I know is when Sarbanes-Oxley came 5 out, you wrote off the IPO thing. It's not even really 6 talked about. And it comes up once in a while, but it's 7 really -- you know, if you've got a business model 8 that's a potential rocket ship, like a Facebook, you 9 know, the other dimension. And you really got to get 10 into the details. 11 I would really recommend that in the research 12 that's done you -- there's -- you drill down into some 13 of the more detailed aspects of this round of psychology 14 of the CEO and the board and the VC, then map it across, 15 you know, all those metrics over the years. 16 And I would bet one of the things you find are 17 things like, you know, the -- depending on what market 18 you were in, if you were in the B-to-C world, well, you 19 know, that's something where you can go public, you can 20 remain independent, and you could have a grand slam 21 because you're selling to an emotional buyer, right. You 22 look at the IPOs, Facebook, LinkedIn, Groupon, they're 23 selling to an emotional buyer, to consumer. 24 If you switch over to the B to B world, right, if 25 you're an enterprise software company or a SaaS 0250 1 provider, look at the competition, and your likelihood 2 of surviving as an independent company and growing and 3 getting anybody interested in your stock, right, and I 4 think what you find is there has been massive 5 aggregation in the tech space. There's going to be ten 6 big companies left on the planet at this rate, right. 7 Most of them have acronyms for names. 8 And at the end of the day, right, if you are 9 going to remain independent, those are your competitors 10 in the B to B world. Our smallest competitor has a $64 11 billion market cap. That's the small one, right. 12 So can we compete with them? Not over the 13 long-term, right. 14 Well, what we and most of the CEOs I talk to 15 that are in this kind of boat, what they do themselves 16 is outsource R&D for big companies, right. 17 What we're trying to do is build a product and 18 out-engineer them, get it to market. Can we ever 19 compete globally when they dominate the channels of 20 distribution and all the servicing integration partners? 21 No. Right. All you can do is put yourself on the 22 tracks, right, and hopefully get a bidding war going 23 between a few of them that all want that piece. 24 I think it'd be really interesting to map all 25 these charts against the M&A in the growth of these big 0251 1 companies. 2 Again, in our space, you know, if you look at 3 the big companies in this -- and I think someone 4 mentioned a recent IBM acquisition in this group. Just 5 look at the size and scale of these companies. On one 6 chart where it said what are the impacts -- the 7 impactful items to people wanting to go public or remain 8 public. One of them was this -- it was -- I can't 9 remember the term, but it was about the scope, the 10 example that was given earlier about the refrigeration 11 truck, right, the ice cream and the milk. 12 I think -- and that was rated as not 13 important. I think that is massively important, because 14 out there in the competitive world, what happens is you 15 have a product that -- and you look at profitability. 16 So this chart that shows small companies aren't 17 profitable. Well, yeah, because you have to fund 18 overcoming that channel dominance and effective 19 monopolies of control in these customers in the B to B 20 world. 21 I would suspect that's not true when you look 22 at consumer-oriented target markets, although in some it 23 may be true. 24 But absolutely in tech, B to B, it's all about 25 distribution, right. And those are very tightly 0252 1 controlled quasi, almost cartels, right, that used to -- 2 what was the saying, right, you don't get fired for 3 buying IBM. Well, you don't get fired for buying HP, 4 you don't get fired for buying Dell. Right. You could 5 get fired for buying Pipeline, because nobody knows who 6 we are. We're very specialized and, in our niche, the 7 best at what we do. 8 But there's a very kind of dominant evolving 9 market of really big companies that nobody wants to 10 compete with. You certainly wouldn't want to go public 11 and get hammered for a couple of quarters. And when you 12 look at what your marketing spend is to overcome some of 13 these distribution channels, that's why the 14 profitability is low. 15 So bottom line to me is -- and again, you 16 know, I don't think it's a Charlie-ism. I think it 17 would be great to, you know, let's do a survey and talk 18 to all these people and they'll say the same thing, is 19 you're crazy for going public, right. You built some 20 value, try to lock down a patent or two, get a little 21 bit of leverage, and then you sell. 22 MR. GRAHAM: Now, when you say you're crazy 23 for going public, how would things have to change? 24 MR. SUNDLING: Well, so that's a great 25 question. And I've been -- and I'm trying to remain 0253 1 optimistic, believe it or not, and trying to think what 2 if, again, someone was trying to convince me to go 3 public, what would have to change? 4 And, you know, it's actually pretty tough to 5 say because I think that the fundamental market has 6 changed and your chances of survival in a public market, 7 it depends on the size of the company. If you're sub 50 8 million, one of the great things about being a small 9 private company is you don't have to tell anybody what 10 our revenue is or what anybody is getting paid, and all 11 these things that competitors are going to pull right 12 out of your Qs and Ks and use against you, maybe even 13 customers will. Our customers are very, very large 14 companies. You know, so there's the dimension of 15 disclosure and risk, right. So you put financials out 16 there for the world to see, again, depending on what 17 kind of shape you're in and what you're trying to do, 18 you may not want to do that. 19 What would need to change, right, is -- it's 20 probably a whole bunch of things, but at the end of the 21 day, they all add up to risk mitigation. If I were to 22 go to my investors and say, hey, I want to go public -- 23 I mean, I don't even know how that story could be sold, 24 right, because the other thing that's happening -- 25 MR. GRAHAM: Certainly not in today's 0254 1 environment. 2 MR. SUNDLING: Well, you can't. And a big 3 part of that reason is the lucrative nature of M&A, 4 right. So the private company deals that are getting 5 done, the volume of them, the multiples being paid by 6 strategics. You know, unless you think you've got 7 something that's going to be a 20-year business, right, 8 and exist in perpetuity -- which I think is not in the 9 mind set anymore, right. 10 And I can remember the days, right, and I'm 11 sure y'all do as well, that the only discussion ever was 12 about building a great company that's going to last a 13 hundred years, and it's going to be billions. And 14 everyone was, you know, drinking the same Kool-Aid. 15 Well, Kool-Aid these days is, right, highly 16 leveraged investments that even VCs, they're doing these 17 tiny rounds. They want to just see proofs and 18 technology, very incremental, and they're looking for 19 the tenbagger that might be under a 50 to 100 million 20 dollar total deal, right, which means total investment 21 is going to be 2 to 10 million. 22 That's the other thing that we're seeing is, 23 you know, the -- other than the very rare, exceptionally 24 large transactions, that lower end market is really 25 research for big companies, right. 0255 1 One of the -- I mean, one of the potential 2 theoretical remedies to the whole thing is what was 3 discussed earlier, which is just a completely different 4 alternative market, right. 5 The one that I used to follow that was 6 interesting is this whole London AIM thing. I don't 7 know if you guys pay much attention to it. But I 8 remember some British bankers telling me, yes, just the 9 public venture capital, right. Is the reporting -- you 10 report once a year. You get this thing called a nomad, 11 who's your nominated advisor. All the requirements are 12 very low. And everybody knew that effectively this 13 thing was just a way to raise money. Easy, very low 14 regulations, didn't distract you from your business, and 15 gave you some kind of liquidity. 16 It's not, you know, an actively traded, you 17 know, volume traded stock to where all the investors are 18 liquid, but now you've at least got a vehicle where you 19 can bring in institutions and other things, and founders 20 can liquidate some of their stock. So some kind of 21 alternative vehicle, maybe a modified version of the OTC 22 would be interesting. I don't know. 23 But, you know, I think in the U.S. in general, 24 nobody would argue that we really kind of put the 25 regulatory screws to all of this. And now it's got 0256 1 to be spun back. But even after they are, I would argue 2 it's a five-year marketing job to unwind it, right. So 3 is everybody prepared for another decade of slow small cap 4 IPOs? Because I think realistically that's probably 5 what's going to happen if you fixed it today. 6 MS. JACOBS: I didn't hear. I want to make 7 sure, though. I did hear you say that the regulations 8 are as much an impediment as market structure? 9 MR. SUNDLING: Yeah. I think there's 10 multiple -- yeah, regulations, market structure, and 11 whatever you want to call it, the change in psychology 12 of the executives and to some extent the investors. 13 MS. JACOBS: Right, the macro. 14 MR. SUNDLING: Yeah. 15 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. David, I know, has got to 16 leave pretty soon. 17 So before you do, anything you want to say 18 besides goodbye? 19 MR. BOCHNOWSKI: It's been a great day. You 20 know, the evidence that we saw is that there was a 21 period when the IPO market was something everybody 22 wanted to do. Clearly we're not going to go back to that 23 time. There's no way to change things that have 24 occurred. 25 I believe that Professor Schwartz, he'll be in 0257 1 my will, too, because I think at least he's given us a 2 path to whatever the future is going to be. I think we 3 have to think about what that future is going to look 4 like. 5 Many of these issues don't really directly 6 relate to me as a CEO because I'm a community banker. 7 Where it does relate is that we know that the IPOs 8 created more jobs over time, and that gets back to what 9 I do every day. And the more jobs there are, the 10 happier bankers are. 11 So I think we've got to figure out a way to 12 come up with a new regime, and I think that's what 13 you're suggesting. And we've got to create whatever 14 that future is so that the economy can continue to 15 thrive. 16 I thought that one of the things I learned 17 today was very instructive to me, and that was when you 18 shifted to the electronic order book. Where that 19 discussion impacts me as a company is that every time 20 our stock has been slammed down -- and we have an 21 average volume of under 200 shares a day -- it's always 22 happened electronically, never happened through the 23 book. 24 And so I think there is that investor class 25 and there's the trader class. The trader class is not 0258 1 helping what we all do every day. And I think that has 2 to be addressed. 3 On scaling, clearly the idea that my company 4 or any company that is of our size has to report at the 5 same level and do the same things every day that the 6 very large companies that do offer systemic risk to the 7 American economy and to investors is the risk management 8 portion of this that I think we need to address as a 9 group. And we have to be sure that the risks that some 10 of us take on and the rewards that some of us have for 11 taking on those risks are scaled appropriately to 12 whatever might happen within the economy that would be a 13 negative to the overall status of our nation. 14 But some of us clearly don't offer those 15 systemic risks and shouldn't have to go through the same 16 things as those who do. So that's why I applaud what 17 you -- the seed you have planted. 18 MR. GRAHAM: Milton. 19 MR. CHANG: I think we're not going to roll 20 the clock back. I think if we can fight them, I think 21 we should think of ways to supersede them. 22 My prediction is that the IPO market is going to 23 continue to be in bad shape for the foreseeable future. 24 Because if you look at the feeding part of it, in terms 25 of where VCs park their money, is mostly in the web and 0259 1 mobile space, where tends to be very -- just very little 2 product differentiation where the ticks are off. And 3 you're going to have very few IPOs for big ones. Where 4 on the manufacturing side, product side, there are room 5 for differentiation; therefore, there are many IPOs. 6 So I don't think that's going to be changed in 7 the sense that's the investment trend on the feeding 8 end. 9 And I think the objective is about job 10 creation and economy. And if that's the case, M&A is 11 probably just as efficient, if not more so, than IPO, 12 because scaling is much more efficient in a big 13 corporation. 14 So M&A in fact is a very efficient way of 15 scaling the businesses once it's incubated in a small 16 company. 17 And I think the capital formation is really 18 the key to growth. And I think that's in fact the 19 charter of the SEC. 20 And I think two personal experience that's not 21 being discussed: One is the -- in the good old days you 22 can walk into Cisco and you say, I want to develop this 23 technology. And you can come out with an agreement 24 where you will be bought when your objective is 25 accomplished. And you use that piece of paper to go out 0260 1 and raise money. 2 That can no -- that's no longer allowed 3 because that's kind of external R&D funding. So you 4 have to write it off on your bottom line. And that's a 5 detriment to -- in terms of getting VC funding. 6 And then the other one is the allocation of 7 the R&D tax credit or tax loss. Those are great 8 incentives to attract investment capital into the 9 startup community, and both of those are gone today. 10 So I think those are the systemic issue that 11 we can really sort of recommend to make a difference. 12 MR. GRAHAM: You know, this -- you know, we 13 talked about scaling. And it relates directly to 14 capital formation because we've got companies -- I mean, 15 there's a bigger hurdle than that, you know, with 16 companies like Charlie's who say they don't want to go 17 public. Nonetheless, that is -- that is a -- that does 18 provide headway for people who do want to at least 19 consider the IPO. 20 Then in terms of -- we talked about capital 21 formation, and kind of related to that is that if I can 22 save a million dollars in compliance costs, that's a 23 million dollars I can use in my company. 24 And it really -- you know, it really seems to 25 me that -- that when you think about how you can 0261 1 accomplish this, that more and more we should be 2 thinking in terms of the principles we apply in this 3 context. Because it seems to me that kind of a basic, 4 you know, tenet of what we're dealing with here is 5 disclosure and what is and what is not material. And it 6 seems to me like that materiality doesn't necessarily 7 depend on market cap or revenue or how long you've been 8 public. 9 MR. CHANG: I think I'm in 100 percent 10 agreement with Charles. What he essentially said is 11 take it one inch at a time, five feet at a time. That's 12 the back end. The front end is the capital formation. 13 MR. GRAHAM: Right. But my question is in 14 context for anyone to respond to, investors in 15 particular: What is out there in the way of compliance 16 that you see that you don't need? 17 MS. JACOBS: Here's a question: For those of 18 you that invest in public companies, is the disclosure 19 in and around conflict minerals going to be material? 20 That's a simple one, I think. But you have to tell me 21 or -- because we had this discussion several months ago 22 when we even discussed the CD&A, pay-for-performance, 23 the frequency of pay-for-performance. I mean, the list 24 goes on and on. 25 MR. CHACE: I can tell you that the way we use 0262 1 public documents, the research companies, the 10-Ks and 2 the 10-Qs, for the numbers, for the business 3 description, for the footnotes to financial statements, 4 the management discussion and analysis which I think is relatively 5 straightforward. 6 (Outside noise.) 7 The compensation disclosure is much less. I 8 think it's really (inaudible) put together. It's not an 9 area where we typically focus -- I can't speak for every 10 investor, obviously, but I think that we spend a lot of 11 time talking about it, try to gauge their motivations 12 from that. Compensation is a part of that. It really 13 is (inaudible). We're looking for people that are 14 founders, inside owners as well. (Inaudible) complex 15 pay structure. Conflict minerals is (inaudible). 16 MS. JACOBS: Okay. So we got one. 17 MR. DENNIS: I think the question on the 18 conflict minerals is, that’s in the law, right. Congress 19 wrote that. It wasn't written for customer protection. 20 I think the question is to the SEC staff: Do 21 we have any flexibility here? Because the law is pretty 22 clear. As I understood it, it said you will do this. 23 And so does the SEC staff have any ability to exempt 24 companies under a certain size? I don't know the answer 25 to that. 0263 1 MR. NALLENGARA: The final rule, which was 2 adopted late last month, didn't exempt any company. And the 3 reason for that is expressed in the final rule, is that 4 the congressional mandate in Dodd-Frank didn't 5 provide -- didn't contemplate anything other than all 6 reporting companies have to do the -- have to do 7 disclosure. There is some phasing provided for smaller 8 companies. 9 MR. DENNIS: You know, it's like a 10 four-year -- 11 MR. NALLENGARA: Four-year. 12 MR. DENNIS: So we got four years to get 13 Congress to change the law, kind of how I -- 14 MR. NALLENGARA: Well, it's not really four 15 years. After doing four years, they don't have to -- you 16 know, there's a varying -- without getting into -- and I 17 think we're all in painful detail of the rule, there are 18 some variances, there are some stages of work that a 19 company would have to do. Whether you can certify and 20 get an audit saying that your stuff is conflict-free is 21 at one end. 22 And a smaller company can for four years 23 effectively say they haven't been able to determine 24 whether it's conflict-free. So it's still work for them 25 to do, but it's a part of -- it's part of an elaborate 0264 1 transition mechanism, smaller companies have a longer 2 transition. 3 So I mean, this is -- and I don't think 4 anyone, at least -- I'm from the staff perspective, I 5 think the Commissioners, I don't think anyone is 6 thinking this is disclosure that an investor determining 7 whether they're going to buy or sell its security is 8 looking for. This is not that. This is -- I mean, 9 that's not what the purpose -- I don't think that's what 10 the purpose of -- if you look at Dodd-Frank, that wasn't 11 the intended purpose. 12 So when you look at materiality, it's probably 13 not the best lens to be looking at this Act, because I 14 don't think that was the lens that anyone who -- 15 MR. DENNIS: But I think it does show a 16 dangerous trend of Congress using this organization as a 17 way to social engineer something that is not in its 18 mandate, not in its charter. And I don't expect you to 19 comment. 20 MR. NALLENGARA: No, no, and I'm grateful it's 21 not webcast, so -- 22 MR. DENNIS: We can make a recommendation 23 that -- maybe the recommendation, Christine, is that we 24 try to seek congressional action on this in some way. 25 That's probably the answer to this. Maybe that's how we 0265 1 form our recommendation. 2 MS. JACOBS: Well, okay. That's one 3 suggestion. But then I'll throw another one out to the 4 folks that are investors. XBRL. 5 MR. CHACE: I am not certain how much we use 6 it directly. I mean, the word -- and we use basically 7 the filings to plug in our own numbers. It's not clear 8 to me how XBRL makes my life better. We do use a lot of 9 financial information providers that probably benefit 10 from XBRL that we use to download data. So they have 11 some secondary positive effect on us, but not 12 day-to-day. 13 MR. LEZA: Can we get back to jobs, get back to 14 access to capital, which is basically why this group was 15 formed for. I like to separate it in two ways here to 16 make a comment, one from the private side, and one from 17 the public side. 18 From the private side, I was involved in 19 startups in six companies. One of them failed, five 20 were acquired in M&A. Okay. And there was three 21 things that you looked at. And the animal has changed 22 from IPOs, the way I see it. 23 Okay. The first thing you look at, risk. You 24 look at risk. And you kind of evaluate what my options 25 are going public or what my options are going M&A. 0266 1 The second thing you look at is, what kind of 2 money am I going to get based on IPO and based on M&A? 3 If you look at it, M&A has been swinging to 4 where they used to have a multiple one or two, and now 5 they're paying seven or eight. Now, so you kind of look 6 at it and say, I mean, I can get seven or eight. I'm 7 not tied up. There's no locking. I can -- my stock can 8 be, you know, liquid in no time. And since it's a big 9 corporation, I can sell immediately because I don't hold 10 that much of a percentage based on the large 11 corporation. So the animal has changed from the private 12 side. 13 So a lot of the companies that you see, they 14 look at risk, they look at how much money. 15 And then the other problem that they look at, 16 and I think this is one big problem, is all of a sudden 17 you've got two things. From the private side you go in 18 and you look at it, and all of a sudden it becomes 19 performance quarter to quarter. They don't care about 20 the long-term. It's quarter to quarter. And people do 21 not like working like this. When you're private, you're 22 looking at three to five years, and you're making 23 decisions in three to five years. 24 And this thing about, I need to be looking at 25 it quarter to quarter, you spend so much time doing that 0267 1 and trying to see what you need to little tweak and 2 stuff. And you look at this and say, hey, it's a choice 3 here. It's not that -- you know, I can understand some 4 of the presentations and some of the stuff, but I think 5 the pendulum has changed. 6 From the public side, being involved with 7 public companies and market cap all the way from I would 8 say, you know, 70 million all the way to 450 million, 9 you look at that from the private side. 10 And I can understand SoX, you know. And like 11 I said before, when we implemented SoX, for the first 12 two years the expense went up, and it went up quite a 13 bit, you know. 14 But then within the next two or three years, 15 there was certain things that were implemented, and we 16 brought the cost right back to where it was before. 17 Okay. 18 So I don't think that that is something that 19 prevents things from creating a bigger company or adding 20 jobs or stuff like this. I think regulations, yeah, 21 they're an irritation, but I don't think that that's 22 something that keeps the people from thinking 23 differently. 24 I still think the focus -- what becomes 25 important is that access to capital. I need to get more 0268 1 money to do more things. And a lot of times what 2 happens is you're in the public company, you've gone 3 public and you've got money, and it depends how you look 4 at it. 5 In a semiconductor company, we had a company 6 that was sitting there, we were growing double digits, 7 but -- you know, and we had $250 million in cash and we 8 were doing something like -- our revenue was like $80 9 million, and, you know, we were public. 10 But then another company came in and said, 11 look, if we consolidate, we can buy and do this, do 12 that. The numbers were right, so we said, okay, let's 13 do it. It's not that we didn't want to be public; it's 14 just that the economy and the choice became greater by 15 consolidating and selling out. 16 The thing that we have to look at is that both 17 private and public companies create jobs when they have 18 access to capital, and I think that's the thing that we 19 gotta look at more closely and see what we can do to 20 relieve some of the constraints so that people are more 21 freely picking up capital and being able to grow in a 22 faster rate than we can have. 23 MR. GRAHAM: Right. Can't disagree with that. 24 MR. SUNDLING: I think one of the key points 25 in there if I can chime in that I think that can't be 0269 1 lost in this discussion is those multiples and how it's 2 swung. So I remember -- this is not being webcast, 3 right? 4 MS. ZEPRALKA: It's being recorded. 5 MR. GRAHAM: Recorded. 6 MR. SUNDLING: Oh, it's being recorded. Oh. 7 Well, then, I won’t go through that example, but -- 8 There was an event back in around the dot-com 9 boom days. And, you know, we had an offer on the table. 10 And at the time, right, it's exactly what you said, is 11 M&A, the multiples were pretty modest. You know, there 12 were 3X, and there were -- there were, though, these 13 ridiculous dot-com deals happening. 14 But on the M&A side, you could expect a 15 reasonable return, but there was no limit on an IPO 16 because you'd have -- and there were a couple 17 companies -- won't name their tickers, but one of my 18 favorites had 63 million in revenue and a market cap was 19 $16 billion, right. And so everybody -- you know, we 20 all knew deep down that wasn't going to last, but that's 21 what you were going after. 22 Now it's all about the alternatives. So, you 23 know, we had some nice offers, and we turned them down, 24 which today, these offers would be -- you know, you'd 25 jump on in a second, right. But it was because of the 0270 1 alternative opportunity and an IPO was worth the risk 2 and all the other things that come with it, because it 3 was just ridiculously different what you could do if you 4 had a successful IPO you -- taken out early. 5 And that's changed, right. So now it's more 6 about those multiples are up, because look at who the 7 buyers are. Just check the balance sheets of all these 8 big -- they're sitting in aggregate hundreds of billions 9 of dollars in cash looking for something to do. They're 10 all on buying frenzies, right. They're taking all the 11 components they need to grow these massive companies. 12 And on the other side, you've got this crazy, 13 regulated, painful thing called being public. You know, 14 it's a pretty easy choice, right. And so I'll leave 15 that one alone. 16 I promised Lona I'd complain about one more 17 thing before I left, which is this accredited investor. 18 Okay. Time to do that? Just so we can get some 19 specific recommendations. 20 MR. NALLENGARA: Sure, yeah, any -- yeah. 21 More complaining is good. 22 MR. LEZA: With recommendations. 23 MR. NALLENGARA: Yeah, yeah, if you're going 24 to complain, yeah. 25 MR. SUNDLING: Around 506 which -- so the good 0271 1 news is these reforms around 506 are phenomenal, right. 2 To actually be able to tell somebody that you're selling 3 stock, that's pretty good, right? And we did a PPM and 4 we had to go through all this stuff, and then you get to 5 this notion of accredited investor and who is it. And 6 whatever the -- 200,000 now a year, expecting it for the 7 next year or a million in net assets exclusive of real 8 estate. 9 MR. NALLENGARA: Of your house, your home. 10 MR. SUNDLING: Of your primary residence? 11 MR. NALLENGARA: Yeah. 12 MR. SUNDLING: Okay. So the measurement 13 you're looking for is a sophisticated investor that can 14 evaluate risk, right. I think nobody would argue that 15 just because you have a million bucks in the bank or you 16 make $200,000 a year doesn't necessarily make you a 17 sophisticated investor. And if there are a lot of 18 people -- you can have a Harvard MBA graduating that's 19 making, you know, 90K doing some analysis work down the 20 road that knows more about your market and your business 21 than anybody else on earth, and you can't take a $10,000 22 check from him, it just doesn't seem like that's the 23 measurement, right. 24 That maybe these things were thrown out there 25 because somebody needed to -- you had to have some kind 0272 1 of measurement, but what can we do to ease that? Because 2 when you talk about -- someone in here mentioned, I 3 think it was this young man here, cutting off access and 4 limiting investment to certain people. I would argue -- 5 MR. GRAHAM: You can still take money from 6 that Harvard professor, you just can't rely on Reg D. 7 MR. SUNDLING: Okay. 8 MS. SMITH: He can be part of your crowd 9 funding. 10 MR. SUNDLING: Yeah. So anyhow, some look at 11 making that a little smarter on identifying what exactly 12 is an accredited investor. 13 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. I want to make sure 14 everyone has a chance to comment before we run out of 15 time. I haven't heard from Karen or Catherine or 16 Kathleen. 17 MS. MOTT: I just wanted to just maybe 18 summarize what I thought when I read all this material 19 and after listening today is that I think there's an 20 amalgam of factors that are contributing to the issues 21 we're dealing with in the marketplace. And obviously 22 things need to be addressed. 23 Where I see critical issues in my industry, 24 because we're at a point where we invest -- we expect 25 VCs to follow on and invest in some of our companies. 0273 1 And in the two areas are life sciences, biotech, I put 2 them together, and clean tech that are very capital 3 intensive. They're going to require VC money. 4 And when you have a contraction of the 5 industry, what we're seeing is that a lot of these 6 companies aren't getting appropriately funded, and that 7 could really make a difference because there's no 8 incentive, the IPO incentive has been taken away. Or 9 not taken away, but it has diminished. 10 So we have great concerns about when we're 11 making our investment decisions, wow, this is clean 12 tech, maybe we should not invest in this because we 13 don't think we're going to get the follow-on funding 14 that is going to be required for this company. 15 So my concerns, of course, are how much that's 16 going to impact those kinds of companies. 17 And my other concern is something else I'm 18 seeing, is in the M&A market. One of our local 19 companies got 40 million in VC funding, was acquired 20 by –- it was called Renal Solutions. It was a home dialysis 21 kit. Acquired by Fresenius in Germany. Fresenius 22 shelved the company because it was going to disrupt the 23 marketplace. So they paid $200 million to shelve it. So 24 it didn't create jobs, some people made some money, and 25 it made no difference in the marketplace. So, and it 0274 1 could have made a difference in people's lives. So 2 that's a concern. 3 My third concern is we can't be sitting here 4 with blinders on and not be concerned about what's 5 happening in China, people with lots of money. And I 6 was at a demo, a demo day in my own little town of 7 Pittsburgh, and there were representatives from China 8 there looking to invest in companies and build these 9 companies. And that surprised me because we're not 10 Boston, we're not Silicon Valley. 11 So let's say they find a Charlie, Charlie's 12 company is going to China. Who's going to create -- the 13 wealth that's going to be created is going to be in 14 China, not here, you know, not in my backyard, if that 15 happens. So those are the kinds of things I'm concerned 16 about if we do not address the IPO market. 17 MR. GRAHAM: Kathleen. 18 MS. McGOWAN: I just wanted to talk about life 19 sciences and the biotech industry. There are two sides 20 to the story: to stay private and then to look for an 21 M&A transaction. When you're talking about developing 22 drugs, you're talking about clinical trial studies, 23 which could be hundreds of millions dollars. And then 24 you've got a lot of big pharmaceutical companies. And 25 their R&D organizations have been shut down, so 0275 1 purchasing of -- M&A -- of smaller companies with certain 2 expertise is the way to go and the ability to buy them. 3 So IPOs may not always be an exit. You know, 4 you may not raise all the funds you need to continue 5 clinical trials. It may not be even an exit for the 6 current investors, but, you know, that might be one way 7 of -- one way that's stopping some of the IPOs. 8 But I still think that if you could 9 potentially get an IPO in the market, raise some money, 10 get some big milestones and possibly do a secondary, 11 there's another option of getting additional funds, and 12 then other funding to fund your clinical trials is 13 another option. 14 I think a lot of the JOBS Act will help with 15 reducing some of the required reporting. Because you 16 have to think, some of these small companies have less 17 than 20 people. You can't possibly get all the 18 reporting and all the things up to speed. Yet they 19 still may have a lot of controls in place already to 20 make it, you know, a viable company and to, you know, be 21 reporting similar to what you need to do, which does not 22 have all the head count required and the cost associated 23 with it. Like you said, you know, that money can go 24 into R&D or additional clinical trial, which is to go 25 into reporting. 0276 1 And then I just had some questions on the 2 tick, the size of the tick, which -- size that David was 3 mentioning in, you know, the pilot program and how do 4 you go ahead and do the piloting. 5 Are the back office operations able to 6 handle -- like if you had two different markets and how 7 you would handle different tick sizes in those markets. 8 Kind of getting the – devil is in the details in how 9 would those things work. Those are things I'm not 10 familiar with. So those would be questions that I have. 11 But basically, you know, you have private 12 markets and potential M&A exit and then IP exit -- IPO 13 exit, what those possibilities were. And if it would 14 help smaller companies get into the IPO market, 15 potentially raise additional funds to do clinical 16 trials, I think that that's well worth the effort. But 17 I still have a lot of questions after everything today 18 on, you know, how do you go about doing that. 19 MR. GRAHAM: Well, the good news is that this 20 committee only has to make recommendations. 21 MS. McGOWAN: Right. And I don't know a lot 22 of that. Some of the things David brought up, I don't 23 know some of the back office of how you physically do 24 these things. Are they almost more -- you know, I don't 25 know the logistics behind it. 0277 1 MR. GRAHAM: Right, right. 2 MR. DENNIS: Steven, on that -- at one point 3 we talked about making a recommendation on the high tech 4 companies with very simple operational structures, but 5 large market cap structures. Is that something that 6 we're going to -- 7 MR. GRAHAM: I'm sorry. I'm not recalling. 8 MR. DENNIS: Okay. Maybe I'm thinking of a 9 different group or something. But, you know, I think -- 10 you know, we've exempted Sarbanes -- we've exempted 11 small companies from Sarbanes-Oxley. And there's this 12 group of companies that are high tech, large market caps 13 and very simple operational structures that are not 14 exempted from SoX 404, and does that make sense to 15 recommend something around that? 16 MR. GRAHAM: I'm not sure if we discussed that 17 in this group, or if it was one of the times I was 18 sleeping. 19 MR. DENNIS: Okay. I'm sorry. I'm brain 20 dead. I must have thought about it -- it must have been 21 somewhere else. 22 MR. GRAHAM: But I do think that one of the 23 things that we have to be thinking about in terms of 24 this recommendation is kind of the way things have 25 played out where now we have -- we have -- you know, 0278 1 people essentially kind of acknowledge that the scaling 2 can be a good thing. I mean, it's going to make sense 3 in a lot of contexts. And that's given us smaller reporting companies 4 portion of money. And it's given us the emerging 5 growth company. 6 But, you know, within that are, kind of 7 overlooked, kind of orphans I think in this whole 8 process, are the companies like Chris's company where it 9 doesn't -- it doesn't qualify for any of this stuff. But 10 if she had an IPO with her company and with all the 11 characteristics necessary to qualify as an emerging 12 growth company, she does IPO on December 8, she would 13 qualify for all the benefits. But if she had done an 14 IPO on December 7, she wouldn't. 15 So there's -- not sure how that really kind of 16 plays out in terms of, you know, protection for 17 investors. 18 But I think, you know, certainly a part of 19 this kind of goes back to, you know, kind of the notion, 20 to what extent does it make sense to have, you know, 21 multiple markets? I think that might go to what 22 Kathleen was saying as well. 23 I certainly -- I certainly think that what 24 relief that we have provided for some companies probably 25 could be extended to others. And I also probably made clear that 0279 1 I think it makes some sense in terms of coming up with 2 kind of another market to operate kind of alongside the 3 markets we currently have in place. Definitely might 4 make things easier. 5 Just conceptually or intuitively, I feel if we 6 had a market and it was geared only to accredited 7 investors and so all the disclosure was simplified 8 accordingly, but nonetheless, who was that you -- you 9 were going to have access to in fact every accredited 10 investor in the world, that you could probably build 11 something. But that's just -- I mean, it seems to me 12 those are -- those are things that we're going to need 13 to explore. 14 Yes. 15 MR. BORER: It's hard to make a recommendation 16 that they should study the fact that we're all really 17 worried about the IPO market being dead and being unfair 18 out there for small companies. 19 One thing I think that makes a lot of sense to 20 some of the stuff that has been talked about today seems 21 to be recommendation that the SEC studies this or it 22 actually looks at regulation can do this as opposed to 23 legislation. 24 But I think making all the companies who are 25 already public subject to similar reporting requirements 0280 1 that were created in the JOBS Act for that first five 2 years seems like a no-brainer. It absolutely seems like 3 a no-brainer. Why somebody didn't say, hey, why are we 4 putting shackles on these people already because they 5 were dumb enough to already get public and letting these 6 others, you know, run without that problem, that seems 7 like a very easy recommendation. And it's not just 8 because I'm sitting next to Chris. 9 The other thing with respect to -- David is 10 gone now -- Wall Street and the indicting statistic up 11 there today was how many book running managers were 12 there ten years ago versus how many there are today? And 13 it doesn't have anything to do with the fact there's 14 high speed trading taking up the gap. They don't bring 15 companies, you know, public. Morningstar is not 16 bringing companies public. That's just a 17 misunderstanding in the market. 18 If there's anything that can be done to create 19 more H&Qs, Alex Browns, Behrman Sells, Sutros, Adbest, 20 Tucker Anthonys, you know, all these guys, we should try 21 to do it, or else the government is going to have to 22 step in with something like Community Reinvestment Act 23 and say to these big brokerage firms, unless you guys do 24 these 20 small IPOs a year, we're not going to let you 25 do business with the treasury, okay, in the market. And 0281 1 I don't think that would make sense. It didn't work with 2 big banks, it's not going to work with brokerage. 3 Pick up something specific. If it's tick 4 size, I don't see any downside to it. It may be 5 politically unpopular because people would say, well, if 6 mom and pop investor might by paying another -- you 7 know, a higher commission than they did through -- they 8 are right now through Scottrade. Scottrade at 5.95 isn't 9 giving them any service. It's a wonderful execution 10 platform, but there's no service. And it's dried up the 11 small end of the market, not only for the IPOs, because 12 those firms don't exist anymore to bring them, but also 13 the execution and follow-on. 14 It was -- this morning I think it was David 15 said, he's been on desks, he's run desks. I'm not going 16 to put up $10 million to take a block of stock because I 17 can't pay 25 cents. I can make 1 cent on the upside and 18 $2 on the downside as far as per share. It just won't 19 happen. 20 And you can regulate all you want, but if the 21 regulation makes it so that the people you're regulating 22 have no incentive to take the risk unless you force them 23 to take that risk through some mandate, they won't do 24 it, we go home. I think that's what's taking place. 25 So either investigating or actually 0282 1 implementing something, even if it's on a test or trial 2 basis with this tick size, voluntary or algorithmic or 3 otherwise, it's -- you know, it's a little expression, 4 light one candle, you know, as opposed to cursing the 5 darkness. Because if we just say, let's encourage more 6 small brokerage firms to get in business and see if they 7 do IPOs, we're going to be too old to see the results. 8 It won't happen. 9 So those are two specific things I would 10 suggest we take a look at. 11 MR. GRAHAM: Agreed, agreed. 12 MS. JACOBS: Feel the same? 13 MS. SMITH: I totally agree with everything 14 John said. I think he's spot on. 15 MR. GRAHAM: You got to give us more than 16 that, Karen. 17 MS. SMITH: Well, I -- 18 MS. JACOBS: We'll take the I agree. 19 MS. SMITH: No, I appreciate it because, I 20 mean, I've been struggling today with what is our 21 mandate, like what this committee’s mandate, now given the 22 changes that happened since we first met around this 23 time last year because the JOBS Act, all the things that 24 have transpired since then. So I appreciate John 25 articulating it in the way he did. I think those are 0283 1 two very concrete recommendations that we could actually 2 make. 3 MS. GREENE: I'll jump in real quick. I know 4 we're out of time. But I absolutely agree with what he 5 said on both counts. The exemptions and things that 6 were done with the JOBS Act doesn't help me, doesn't 7 help Chris, doesn't help existing companies because we 8 were dumb enough to go public, whatever. 9 So but even more so than saying, okay, take 10 all those exemptions and apply them, let every company 11 take them. Well, but I want them longer than five years 12 if I can't get my market cap or my revenue or my assets 13 or whatever up over some amount. 14 So as Chris said at the beginning where that 15 75 million market cap, which I really appreciate right 16 now, because we're under that, but if we crowd -- if we 17 get close to that number, my incentive to stay under 18 that market cap is going to be really high, which works 19 totally against investors, because I don't want to do 20 404(b). I don't want to do all those things. 21 So, as Chris said, where 75 million dollar market 22 cap came from as far as exemptions or small 23 reporting companies, I think that needs to be -- 24 certainly needs to be increased. Whoever said the 25 market cap $787 million is 94 percent of the total 0284 1 public company value, and so everybody under -- you know 2 how far away a $787 million market cap is for us? It 3 will never happen in the lifetime of me and the next ten 4 generations, I suspect. So, but that's only 6 percent 5 of the total public company value. And we're -- you 6 know, we help the little companies under 75 million. 7 So I will jump out there and say I like what 8 John said, but I would make that -- those small company 9 exemptions -- set the market cap so if I still don't hit 10 whatever the market cap is in five years, I don't fall 11 off that exemption thing and go, oh, now you're there. 12 So -- based on what Chris said. 13 Some of the things that Charlie said, and 14 these are just -- I wrote them down so I wouldn't ramble 15 too much. So there is no -- as Charlie said, the 16 perception of being public, there's no payoff for that for a 17 small company. Whether that's reality or not, that's the 18 perception. And I don't hear any small public companies 19 talking about how great it is to be public, because 20 there is no -- there's no payoff. 21 Making the IPO process -- and I don't know 22 which one of you guys said it -- making it more 23 attractive doesn't solve the lack of post IPO support 24 for small companies. So you go out and, you know, you 25 do this great IPO, but if you're not -- if you're not 0285 1 the billion dollars or whatever, there's no money in it 2 for the guys that actually used to provide that 3 support -- that support in terms of research and 4 investment banks and whatever. 5 I can't tell you how many investment banks I 6 talked to. I have no deal for you. Well, they're not 7 going to make -- I mean, we trade 5,000 shares a day. 8 They're not going to go for that. I mean, there's 9 nothing -- there's nothing that our company's doing that 10 would incentivize anybody to put any support in, make 11 the phone calls to the brokers, whoever said all that. 12 There's no money there. 13 So until there's money there, and maybe that's 14 tick size, until there's some financial incentive for 15 those guys that used to support public companies, 16 small public companies -- until there's some financial incentive, I don't 17 think -- I don't think anything is ever going to be 18 solved. Companies are not going to go public because 19 they can't get the aftermarket support. Nobody in -- 20 out of the goodness of their heart is going to spend a 21 bunch of time trying to support very small companies, 22 because we're all in everything we do to make money. 23 So I think -- I think tick size is the most 24 concrete suggestion I've heard. And I don't understand 25 it exactly either. I don't know -- if you came to me 0286 1 and said, what do you think your tick size is? I don't 2 know. But why not try it? I mean, it can't get any 3 worse, right? I mean, for us it can't get any worse. 4 For Chris, it probably can’t get worse. So why not try 5 it. It's a concrete suggestion. Let's -- why not throw 6 it out there. 7 Investor interest, it is about increasing 8 shareholder value, which is increasing stock price. That 9 is the result of earnings and growth. Cost to be 10 public, million dollars, whatever. You take that out of 11 your earnings, the pressure on earnings to continue to 12 grow in order to increase your shareholder value, in order 13 to keep investors interested, it's very circular. And 14 the more money you spend on stuff, cost to being public, 15 whatever, reduces earnings. If you're not growing 16 earnings, then the investors aren't interested in you. 17 Again, they're in it to make money, they're not in it 18 because they're feeling generous today. 19 SarbOx, somebody said, had a very small 20 impact. I adamantly disagree with that. But that may 21 be perception now more than anything. SarbOx, the 22 idea why public companies don't -- or why private 23 companies don't want to go public. SarbOx is a huge 24 issue. And whether that's reality or not, the 25 perception is it's a huge issue. I don't want to deal 0287 1 with the SarbOx stuff, so -- 2 And then even if the original reason for 3 wanting to go public is to raise capital, don't we all 4 want to get -- and I throw this out. I'm tired and 5 maybe this doesn't make sense. But don't we all want to 6 get to where we don't need to raise money? I mean, 7 don't we want to grow our companies to where they're 8 organically growing to support or growing enough that we 9 can support our growth internally with organic cash flow 10 and all that, as opposed to having to go back out to the market 11 to garner more -- to raise more capital? 12 So capital formation may be -- or capital 13 raising may be a viable reason to go public to start 14 with. But I know, in my mind, I would eventually want 15 to outgrow that anyway. Once you outgrow that and you 16 don't need to raise money, as Richard said, we have so 17 much cash on the balance sheet, then you have no deal 18 for anybody to do anything for you, so, you know, again 19 it's circular. There's no support. 20 MS. JACOBS: So then why go public? 21 MS. GREENE: Yeah. I mean -- 22 MS. JACOBS: You can’t get out, you’re going to get sued -- 23 MS. GREENE: Or you're going to leverage your 24 company so bad to get out that -- yeah. So 25 recommendation is raise the $75 million market cap on 0288 1 small reporting companies up to -- I don't know, I mean, 2 787 million sounds like a great number, but, you know, 3 I'll take 500 million or whatever. I think that's a 4 great recommendation. 5 Tick size. The only concrete thing, I mean, 6 that I've really heard that might help the aftermarket 7 support for those people that can actually do something 8 with your stock, the market makers and the traders and 9 all that, why not recommend that and see what the SEC 10 comes up with? 11 MS. JACOBS: Any other -- any discussion 12 around the 787 million market cap? 13 DR. RITTER: I've got a catchy acronym. We 14 call it the "BOEING" amendment. 15 MR. DENNIS: The problem with -- if you go up 16 to 787 million, and I'm trying to remember the 17 statistics we looked back four, five years ago, Gerry. 18 But the 75 million, I believe, came from, it was 1 19 percent of the market cap, is where that -- I thought 20 that's where we kinda came up with that recommendation. 21 Because it was 25 million at one point. The 787 22 million, although it's 6 percent of the market cap, it's 23 something like 80 percent of the number of public 24 companies. 25 So if you exempt 80 percent of the public 0289 1 companies out there from Sarbanes-Oxley, and you've kind 2 of done an end run around Congress and the law, and I think 3 you get -- I think it's easy to say. I think it's hard 4 to go down and say, Congress adopted a law that said 5 public companies have to do this and the SEC is going to 6 exempt 80 percent of the public companies out there. 7 MS. GREENE: Well, I think lower the number, 8 then. Go to, I don't know, go to 75 million. 9 MR. LEZA: Go to 250 million, like I said 10 before. 11 MR. DENNIS: I'm just saying it's harder than 12 just that. But -- 13 MS. JACOBS: Right. But the law -- but 14 Congress itself has exempted companies up to a billion 15 in revenue, which I don't consider emerging, but that's 16 how they've identified them. 17 MR. DENNIS: First five years of their 18 existence, right. 19 MS. JACOBS: That's right. 20 MR. GRAHAM: Yeah. 21 MS. JACOBS: Yeah. 22 MR. GRAHAM: So you've raised a very good 23 point. And I think that one of the reasons why we 24 frequently have issues is that people kinda don't 25 normally -- they're really unable to foresee the 0290 1 unforeseen consequences. And I think that's one of the 2 things that I want to make sure that we do as a 3 committee, make recommendations, perhaps raise certain 4 issues that were raised. 5 We are past time to -- wrap things up. Has 6 everyone had a chance to comment? 7 (No audible response.) 8 MR. GRAHAM: What I would like to -- I've 9 heard -- again, there are a number of things that we 10 talked about. And I think that there is -- the seeds 11 have been planted, I think, for a number of 12 recommendations. Certainly there are two or three things 13 that are relatively concrete on the table. And that is 14 the tick size. One has to do with expanding the -- expanding 15 the relief that was provided under the JOBS Act for a 16 broader group of small public companies, which just 17 happen to have gone public before December 8 and -- am I 18 missing one? 19 MR. DENNIS: Conflict minerals. Let's put 20 conflict minerals. I mean, I'd put it on just because I 21 think conflict -- 22 MS. JACOBS: I don't think we have a thing to 23 lose. 24 MR. DENNIS: Well, I think Congress doesn't 25 read these reports. 0291 1 MS. JACOBS: Yes, no. 2 MR. GRAHAM: We'll make recommendations to the 3 SEC, so I'm not sure. 4 MR. DENNIS: I don't know how we word it, 5 but -- 6 MR. GRAHAM: I'm not sure if our mandate says 7 to do that. 8 MS. JACOBS: But I think we can go on record 9 as recommending -- 10 (Talking simultaneously.) 11 MR. GRAHAM: (Inaudible.) 12 MS. JACOBS: -- an exemption. 13 No, that's an action. It's not going against 14 the law, right? Can't we recommend -- can't we say 15 something about an exemption? 16 MR. LEZA: As long as you define it as a 17 recommendation, you can say whatever you want. 18 MS. JACOBS: Exactly. 19 And I have one follow-on for Leroy. 20 Leroy, there are several studies out there, 21 one in particular is a high state and the couple of 22 others that have defined small reporting companies, and 23 they range from 250 million to 700 million, and maybe 24 what we could do is sort of hold to find out a 25 propensity of what that market cap should be. 0292 1 MR. DENNIS: Yeah, you can -- 2 MS. JACOBS: You understand? 3 MR. DENNIS: Yeah. There's all kinds of 4 statistics out there, so what number of companies you're 5 going to impact. 6 MR. GRAHAM: What I was about to say was we 7 might do kind of thinking about maybe doing what we did last 8 year with respect to what is that -- what is the 9 recommendation that we said we approved telephonically? 10 MS. ZEPRALKA: That was Reg D. 11 MR. GRAHAM: Was that Reg D? I'm thinking 12 about when we can have our next meeting. And obviously 13 next month is October, which means into the holidays. 14 Not going to do anything next month, November, December. 15 But it might make some sense to formulate some 16 recommendations around these few items, then get them 17 out to the group. 18 MS. JACOBS: Oh, well, there's some very 19 practical reasons. Because those of us that are public 20 in January of 2013, several of these exemptions, 21 Say-on-Pay, frequency of Say-on-Pay, we have no 22 reprieves, so we are under a deadline as public 23 companies. 24 MR. GRAHAM: So we're going to make a 25 recommendation. That's not going to be changed by that. 0293 1 MS. JACOBS: No, but really nice to have a 2 place card holder out there. Correct? We're up against 3 deadlines January 2013, those of you that aren't public. 4 MR. GRAHAM: Okay. Ladies and gentlemen, 5 thank you very much. 6 MS. JACOBS: Thank you. 7 (Whereupon, at 4:17 p.m., the meeting was 8 concluded.) 9 * * * * * 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 0294 1 PROOFREADER'S CERTIFICATE 2 In The Matter of: MEETING OF SEC ADVISORY COMMITTEE ON 3 SMALL AND EMERGING COMPANIES 4 File Number: OS-265-27 5 Date: Friday, September 7, 2012 6 Location: San Francisco, CA 7 8 This is to certify that I, Donna S. Raya, 9 (the undersigned), do hereby swear and affirm that the 10 attached proceedings before the U.S. Securities and 11 Exchange Commission were held according to the record 12 and that this is the original, complete, true and 13 accurate transcript that has been compared to the 14 reporting or recording accomplished at the hearing. 15 16 _______________________ _______________________ 17 (Proofreader's Name) (Date) 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 0295 1 STATE OF CALIFORNIA )ss. 2 ) 3 CITY OF COUNTY OF SAN FRANCISCO ) 4 5 I, SUZANNE I. ANDRADE, CSR NO. 10682, a 6 Certified Shorthand Reporter of the State of California, 7 do hereby certify: 8 That the foregoing proceedings were taken 9 before me at the time and place herein set forth; that a 10 verbatim record of the proceedings was made by me using 11 machine shorthand which was thereafter transcribed under 12 my direction. 13 I further certify that I am not interested in 14 the outcome of said action nor connected with, nor 15 related to, any of the parties in said action. 16 IN WITNESS WHEREOF, I have hereunto set my 17 hand and affixed my signature this 13th day of 18 September, 2012. 19 ________________________________ 20 SUZANNE I. ANDRADE, CSR NO. 10682 21 STATE OF CALIFORNIA 22 23 24 25 0296 1 Diversified Reporting Services, Inc. 2 1101 Sixteenth Street, N.W. 3 2nd Floor 4 Washington, DC 20036 5 6 In the Matter of: MEETING OF SEC ADVISORY COMMITTEE ON 7 SMALL AND EMERGING COMPANIES 8 File Number: OS-265-27 9 Date: Friday, September 7, 2012 10 Location: San Francisco, CA 11 12 This is a letter to inform you that we do not release 13 our tapes and notes. I do maintain them for a period of 14 one (1) year. 15 16 Sincerely, 17 ______________________________ 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25