Subject: File No. S7-24-99 Date: 12/08/2000 10:00 AM Gentlemen: I am writing as a private investor concerned with the regulation of short-selling activities. The following comments pertain to the SEC Concept Release on Short Sales, Release No. 34-42037; File No. S7-24-99, but address several relevant issues not included in the current Concept Release. 1. Daily summaries of short interest data should be made available to the market. The current system of reporting short interest provides only monthly summaries, and these totals are not published until some time after a closing date. Public market participants are thus denied an accurate, up-to-date account of short-selling activity, and even this monthly snapshot becomes increasingly stale with passing time. The mechanics of short-selling require that shares be borrowed from a brokerage institution, and these institutions must keep an internal accounting system to track the borrowed shares. This means that the brokerage institutions as a group have, at all times, much more accurate information on short-selling activity than that available to the public. This creates a structural imbalance of information and gives brokerage institutions a potentially significant edge in trading, by virtue of their more accurate and timely information. For example, suppose that an institution holds a significant position in a certain security, and it observes that a short-selling hedge fund is aggressively borrowing shares for shorting. The institution might choose to dump its long position in anticipation of buying it back later. In contrast, the other market participants have no knowledge of the short-selling attack and see only a decline of the share price. Without knowledge of the true market mechanics at work, some private investors may fear a change of company fundamentals and sell at a loss, but if given information on the increased short-selling activity could choose between riding out the cycle or locking in profits before the price had declined too steeply. The SEC has recently enacted other changes (e.g. regulation FD) intended to level the playing field by providing all market participants with equal access to material information. It is significant to note that the 1991 House Committee report on short-selling recommended that daily short interest summaries be made available to the market, yet nearly 10 years later no action has been taken. As this proposal fits well within the spirit of recent SEC actions, in my opinion a plan to provide daily short interest summaries should be added to the Concept Release. 2. Large individual short positions should require public disclosure, and institutions filing form 13F should be required to disclose both long and short positions. Current regulations require public reporting only for material long positions, but since holders of a short position also have a vested interest (albeit a negative one) in the performance of a company, the disclosure of such short positions would be of interest to other market participants. Due to the mechanics of short-selling, brokerage institutions generally already have significant information as to which entities hold large short positions for a given equity. If this information is not made available to the public, it may create a trading advantage favoring the brokerage institutions over the private investor, with an argument analogous to that made above for the case of daily short interest summaries. As the SEC has indicated its interest in providing all market participants with equal access to material information, requiring disclosure of material short positions would be a positive step in this direction. Such disclosure was recommended in the 1991 House Committee report and was considered by the SEC in a 1991 Concept Release, and in my opinion should be considered for this Concept Release as well. It is interesting to note that the 1991 House Committee report observed a "psychological misperception that short sellers possess much greater manipulative power than they really do." I would suggest that this perception derives from the fact that short-sellers have been allowed to hide their activities behind the delayed reports of short interest, and to work anonymously regardless of the size of their short positions. Once the SEC implements reporting requirements to give all market participants a transparent view of short-selling activities, the public will be in a much better position to assess the true impact of short-selling. 3. The SEC should regulate the issue of voting rights under short-selling in order to preserve a company's right to restrict each share to just one vote. Currently the issue of voting rights for short-sold shares is not regulated by the SEC, and the common practice by brokerage institutions is to forward voting proxies to all shareholders of record, even if their shares have been (in all or part) loaned out and sold short. This practice leads to the situation in which more shares are eligible for a proxy vote than are currently outstanding for the company, due to the diluting effect of short-selling. The presence of these additional votes could possibly distort the results of shareholder voting. It is my understanding that the SEC was asked by congress in 1991 to consider this issue, and decided that no action needed to be taken, for the apparent reason that in many cases only a small fraction of eligible shareholder votes are cast. In my opinion the rationale for this decision, while possibly true for many widely-held equities, is nevertheless flawed, as it fails to consider the potential effect of extra votes on smaller companies with thinly-held equities. For example, the present practice of allowing all shares to vote could conceivably be employed in schemes to manipulate a vote by inflating the number of votes to be cast. Short-sellers could arrange for related parties to purchase shares in order to cast extra votes and possibly affect the outcome of the process. Such a changed outcome could be materially detrimental to the company, thereby aiding the cause of the short-sellers. As another example, the present reporting regulations for large individual shareholders consider only the net (long minus short) position to trigger the reporting requirement. This would conceivably allow a shareholder to accumulate a large block of shares (5% or greater) for voting purposes, but to evade the reporting requirement by holding a short position offsetting all or part of the long position. The ability to hold such a large voting interest without the corresponding economic interest is certainly contrary to the intent of the reporting requirement. In order to guard against such potential vote manipulation, I would suggest that the SEC adopt a regulation mandating that voting rights for shareholders whose shares have been loaned out for short-selling be proportionally reduced, possibly to zero, to reflect the fraction of shares loaned out. Brokerage institutions holding shares in street name would be responsible for administering the proportional allocation, and would also be required to notify the shareholders whose voting rights had been reduced. Such notification would allow those shareholders desiring to preserve their voting rights to take actions (such as moving the shares to a cash account) to ensure full voting rights in the future. Adopting such a proportional allocation scheme would ensure that the votes available to be cast would match the actual number of shares outstanding. In closing, I hope that the SEC will consider these suggestions in its ongoing review of short-selling regulations. Best Regards, Bill Hawes